of Bard College
Levy Economics
Institute
THE
MACROECONOMIC
EFFECTS OF
STUDENT DEBT
CANCELLATION
Scott Fullwiler, Stephanie Kelton, Catherine Ruetschlin, and Marshall Steinbaum
February 2018
2 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 3
THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF
STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION
Scott Fullwiler, Stephanie Kelton, Catherine Ruetschlin, and Marshall Steinbaum
4 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Table of Contents
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 6
INTRODUCTION 7
SECTION 1: THE ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY OF STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION 9
Social Investment in Higher Education 9
The current state of student debt 10
The social costs of student debt 12
The Distributional Consequences of Student Debt, Student Debt Cancellation, and Debt-Free College 13
The distribution of student debt and debt burden in the cross section 14
The evolution of the distribution of student debt burdens over time 15
What does the evolution of student debt tell us about the labor market? 16
How does student debt interact with longstanding economic disparaties? 16
The real distributional impact of student debt cancellation and free or debt-free college 17
SECTION 2: THE MECHANICS OF STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION 18
The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation Carried Out by the Government 18
Current servicing of student loans from a balance sheet perspective 18
Possible methods of government-financed student debt cancellation 19
The government cancels the Department of Education’s loans all at once 20
The government cancels the Department of Education’s loans as borrowers’ payments come due 21
Government-led debt cancellation where the government assumes payments on student loans issued by 22
private investors
Government-led debt cancellation where the government simultaneously purchases and then cancels loans owned 24
by private investors
Government-led debt cancellation where the government purchases student loans issued by private investors and 25
cancels principal as payments come due
Concluding remarks on government-led cancellation of privately owned student loans 26
Concluding remarks on government-led debt cancellation 26
The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation Carried Out by the Federal Reserve 27
The Federal Reserve purchases the Department of Educations loans 27
Some fundamentals of the Federal Reserve’s remittances and their relevance to student loan cancellation 28
The Federal Reserve cancels the Department of Educations loans all at once 28
The Federal Reserve cancels debt service payments for the Department of Educations loans 29
The Federal Reserve assumes debt service payments for loans owned by private investors 31
The Federal Reserve purchases and cancels loans owned by private investors 32
The Federal Reserve purchases loans owned by private investors and cancels debt service payments 33
Potential options to avoid costs to the federal government of student loan cancellation carried out by the 34
Federal Reserve
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 5
SECTION 3: SIMULATING STUDENT DEBT CANCELLATION 36
Models and Assumptions Used for Simulating Student Debt Cancellation 36
Introduction to the Moody’s model 36
Introduction to the Fair model 37
Assumptions for the simulated student debt cancellation 37
Baseline values and macroeconometric simulation 38
Simulation Results 39
Conclusions from simulations 45
Omitted Benefits and Costs of Student Debt Cancellation 46
Small business formation 46
College degree attainment 47
Household formation 48
Credit scores 48
Household vulnerability in business cycle downturns 48
Moral hazard 49
CONCLUSION 50
APPENDIX A: SIMULATION DATA SERIES 52
APPENDIX B: DEPARTMENT OF EDUCATION LOANS AND THE BUDGET DEFICIT 55
APPENDIX C: DIGRESSION ON THE FED’S OPERATIONS 58
NOTES 61
REFERENCES 64
6 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Executive Summary
1
More than 44 million Americans are caught in a student debt
trap. Collectively, they owe nearly $1.4 trillion on outstanding
student loan debt. Research shows that this level of debt hurts
the US economy in a variety of ways, holding back everything
from small business formation to new home buying, and even
marriage and reproduction. It is a problem that policymakers
have attempted to mitigate with programs that offer refinanc-
ing or partial debt cancellation. But what if something far more
ambitious were tried? What if the population were freed from
making any future payments on the current stock of outstand-
ing student loan debt? Could it be done, and if so, how? What
would it mean for the US economy?
This report seeks to answer those very questions. The
analysis proceeds in three sections: the first explores the current
US context of increasing college costs and reliance on debt to
finance higher education; the second section works through the
balance sheet mechanics required to liberate Americans from
student loan debt; and the final section simulates the economic
effects of this debt cancellation using two models, Ray Fair’s US
Macroeconomic Model (“the Fair model”) and Moody’s US
Macroeconomic Model.
Several important implications emerge from this analysis.
Student debt cancellation results in positive macroeconomic
feedback effects as average households net worth and dispos-
able income increase, driving new consumption and investment
spending. In short, we find that debt cancellation lifts GDP,
decreases the average unemployment rate, and results in little
inflationary pressure (all over the 10-year horizon of our sim-
ulations), while interest rates increase only modestly. Though
the federal budget deficit does increase, state-level budget posi-
tions improve as a result of the stronger economy. The use of
two models with contrasting long-run theoretical foundations
offers a plausible range for each of these effects and demon-
strates the robustness of our results.
A one-time policy of student debt cancellation, in which
the federal government cancels the loans it holds directly and
takes over the financing of privately owned loans on behalf of
borrowers, results in the following macroeconomic effects (all
dollar values are in real, inflation-adjusted terms, using 2016 as
the base year):
2
The policy of debt cancellation could boost real GDP by
an average of $86 billion to $108 billion per year. Over the
10-year forecast, the policy generates between $861 billion
and $1,083 billion in real GDP (2016 dollars).
Eliminating student debt reduces the average unemploy-
ment rate by 0.22 to 0.36 percentage points over the 10-year
forecast.
Peak job creation in the first few years following the elimina-
tion of student loan debt adds roughly 1.2 million to 1.5 mil-
lion new jobs per year.
The inflationary effects of cancelling the debt are macro-
economically insignificant. In the Fair model simulations,
additional inflation peaks at about 0.3 percentage points and
turns negative in later years. In the Moody’s model, the effect
is even smaller, with the pickup in inflation peaking at a triv-
ial 0.09 percentage points.
Nominal interest rates rise modestly. In the early years, the
Federal Reserve raises target rates 0.3 to 0.5 percentage points;
in later years, the increase falls to just 0.2 percentage points.
The effect on nominal longer-term interest rates peaks at 0.25
to 0.5 percentage points and declines thereafter, settling at
0.21 to 0.35 percentage points.
The net budgetary effect for the federal government is modest,
with a likely increase in the deficit-to-GDP ratio of 0.65 to 0.75
percentage points per year. Depending on the federal govern-
ment’s budget position overall, the deficit ratio could rise more
modestly, ranging between 0.59 and 0.61 percentage points.
However, given that the costs of funding the Department of
Educations student loans have already been incurred (dis-
cussed in detail in Section 2), the more relevant estimates
for the impacts on the government’s budget position relative
to current levels are an annual increase in the deficit ratio of
between 0.29 and 0.37 percentage points. (This is explained in
further detail in Appendix B.)
State budget deficits as a percentage of GDP improve by about
0.11 percentage points during the entire simulation period.
Research suggests many other positive spillover effects that are
not accounted for in these simulations, including increases in
small business formation, degree attainment, and household
formation, as well as improved access to credit and reduced
household vulnerability to business cycle downturns. Thus,
our results provide a conservative estimate of the macro
effects of student debt liberation.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 7
Introduction
There is mounting evidence that the escalation of student debt
in the United States is an impediment to both household finan-
cial stability and aggregate consumption and investment. The
increasing demand for college credentials coupled with rising
costs of attendance have led more students than ever before to
take on student loans, with higher average balances. This debt
burden reduces household disposable income and consump-
tion and investment opportunities, with spillover effects across
the economy. At the same time, the social benefits of investment
in higher education—including human capital accumulation,
social mobility, and the greater tax revenues and social contri-
butions that flow from a highly productive population—remain
central to the economic advantages enjoyed by the United States.
In this context, students, educators, and policymakers have
called for a range of solutions to the rising cost of college and
the encumbrance of borrowers. In this report, we examine the
macroeconomic effects of one of the boldest of these propos-
als: a program of outright student debt cancellation financed
by the federal government. If student debt is indeed dampen-
ing household economic activity, we expect liberation from
this debt to produce a stimulus effect that will partially offset
the cost of the program. In fact, we find that cancelling student
debt would have a meaningful stimulus effect, particularly in
the first five years, characterized by greater economic activity as
measured by GDP and employment, with only moderate effects
on the federal budget deficit, interest rates, and inflation over the
forecast horizon. Overall, the macroeconomic consequences of
student debt cancellation demonstrate that a reorientation of US
higher education policy can include ambitious policy proposals
like a total cancellation of all outstanding student loan debt.
Higher education is a valuable social investment, with
research demonstrating social returns up to five times the dollar
amount of public spending in the United States (OECD 2015).
The diffusion of these benefits across the economy makes them
a classic example of positive externalities, a condition in which
individual cost/benefit calculations that omit social benefits will
result in a market failure. In these cases, public investment is
necessary to avoid chronic underinvestment. Yet in the United
States over the past three decades, public funding of higher edu-
cation has been in decline (SHEEO 2015). At the same time,
the increasing need for a college credential to access key labor
market entry positions provided incentives for more students
to take on debt. This student loan debt imposes a significantly
higher burden on household finances than ever before, as stag-
nant real incomes and higher average balances combine to
divert a larger portion of household resources toward debt ser-
vice and away from consumption and investment.
It is possible for the federal government to reduce or remove
the burden of student loan debt as a means of direct support
to household spending. In this report, we examine the mecha-
nisms that facilitate debt cancellation using T-accounts to map
the transactions associated with the program. In a government-
financed cancellation program, the current loan portfolio of the
Department of Education is cancelled and the federal govern-
ment either purchases and cancels or takes over the payments
for privately owned loans. One of the more significant take-
aways here is the realization that, because the loans made by the
Department of Education—which make up the vast majority
of student loans outstanding—were already funded when the
loans were originated, the new costs of cancelling these loans are
limited to the interest payments on the securities issued at that
time. An alternative route, which some have advocated, involves
the Federal Reserve buying up student loan debt and warehous-
ing the losses on its own balance sheet. We consider this option
below, noting that this avenue would most likely require autho-
rization from Congress. Importantly, we also show that any pro-
gram led by the Federal Reserve results in the same consequences
for the federal government’s budget position as a government-
led program—that is, there is no “free lunch that avoids the
budgetary implications of cancelling student debt.
We also simulated the student debt cancellation program
using two macroeconometric models to examine the implica-
tions of cancellation and incorporate feedback effects that go
beyond the balance sheet analysis. The first-round effect of stu-
dent debt cancellation is an increase in the wealth and dispos-
able income of student loan borrowers. These effects translate
to higher spending in a variety of consumption and investment
categories, which represent greater economic activity and pro-
duce additional income, jobs, and tax revenue. We relied on two
macroeconomic models to simulate these effects: Ray Fair of
Yale University’s US Macroeconomic Model (“the Fair model”)
and Moody’s US Macroeconomic Model, the forecasting model
used by Moody’s and Economy.com. The Fair model and the
Moody’s model share a Keynesian short-run theoretical foun-
dation. In the long run, however, the assumed relationships dif-
fer, as Moody’s takes on a “Classical core while the Fair model
8 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
remains fundamentally Keynesian. In addition to two models
with distinct foundational assumptions, we also implemented
two alternative assumptions about the Federal Reserves inter-
est rate response to the debt cancellation stimulus. The use of
models with contrasting long-run theoretical foundations and
alternative scenarios demonstrates the robustness of the results
in this report, and also allows us to present a plausible range for
each of the estimated effects of a federally financed student debt
cancellation.
A program to cancel student debt executed in 2017 results
in an increase in real GDP, a decrease in the average unemploy-
ment rate, and little to no inflationary pressure over the 10-year
horizon of our simulations, while interest rates increase only
modestly. Our results show that the positive feedback effects of
student debt cancellation could add on average between $86 bil-
lion and $108 billion per year to the economy. Associated with
this new economic activity, job creation rises and the unem-
ployment rate declines.
The macroeconomic models used in these simulations
assume an essentially mechanical Federal Reserve response to
lower unemployment. Suppressing this response—in other
words, assuming the Fed does not raise its interest rate target—
provides an upper bound for the range of possible outcomes
associated with more nuanced central bank policy. In fact, both
models forecast little to no additional inflation resulting from
the cancellation of student debt. In the Fair model, inflation
peaks at an additional 0.3 percent and turns negative after 2020,
meaning that debt cancellation reduces inflation in later years.
In the Moody’s model, the inflationary effects are never higher
than 0.09 percent throughout the period. These forecasts sug-
gest that there is room for flexibility in the assumptions made
about Federal Reserve tactics as a response to debt cancellation.
Since even the largest effect on inflation in a single year is of
little macroeconomic significance, it is arguable that the Fed
would not react to the student debt cancellation program by
raising its target interest rate.
Student debt cancellation is a large-scale program in which
the government must repay privately held loans and forego
interest rate payments on the loan portfolio of the Department
of Education. It is reasonable to expect such a program to add to
the federal government’s budget deficit, absent extraordinarily
strong feedback effects from the programs macroeconomic
stimulus. Our simulations show that student debt cancella-
tion raises the federal budget deficit moderately. The average
impacts on the federal deficit in the simulations are between
0.65 and 0.75 percent of GDP per year. However, the more rel-
evant figures for the annual impact on the federal deficit fall in a
range between 0.29 and 0.37 percent of GDP—this accounts for
the fact that, for the Department of Education loans, only debt
service on the securities originally issued will add to current
deficits and the national debt. The simulations, by their nature,
assume the full costs of the foregone principal and interest on
the Department of Education loans are incurred in the cancella-
tion. In Section 3 and Appendix B, we explain the reasons for this
assumption embedded in the simulations (which generates esti-
mates of budget impacts relative to a no-cancellation baseline
scenario) and how the lower, more relevant figures (estimates
of budget impacts relative to current deficit and debt levels) are
arrived at. Only the Fair model enables forecasts of state-level
budget positions, and we find improvements in states budget
positions as a result of the stimulus effects of the debt cancella-
tion. These improvements will reduce the need for states to raise
taxes or cut spending in the event of future recessions.
It is important to note that the macroeconomic models
used in this report cannot capture all of the positive socioeco-
nomic effects associated with cancelling student loan debt. New
research from academics and experts has demonstrated the
relationships between student debt and business formation, col-
lege completion, household formation, and credit scores. These
correlations suggest that student debt cancellation could gener-
ate substantial stimulus effects in addition to those that emerge
from our simulations, while improving the financial positions
of households.
Our analysis proceeds in three sections. Section 1, The
Economic Opportunity of Student Debt Cancellation, explores
the US context of student borrowing, including reductions in
public investment in higher education and the rising cost of
a college degree, the social costs of rising debt, and the distri-
butional implications of debt and debt cancellation. Section
2, “The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation, explains
the instruments of debt relief, whether enacted by the fed-
eral government or its central bank (the Federal Reserve), and
demonstrates the balance sheet effects of debt cancellation on
the government, the Federal Reserve, banks, borrowers, and
private lenders. Finally, Section 3, “Simulating Student Debt
Cancellation, measures the effects of the program on key mac-
roeconomic variables using simulations in two models—the
Fair model and Moody’s model—under alternative assump-
tions, and examines the costs and benefits of student debt relief
that are omitted from the models.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 9
Section 1: The Economic
Opportunity of Student Debt
Cancellation
In the United States, attaining a college degree has long been
viewed as a safe investment for individuals and for the nation
as a whole. The funding of higher education from both public
and private sources exemplifies the joint character of this invest-
ment, and a strong system of public education has conferred
broad social and economic benefits. Yet over the past three
decades our common commitment to education has broken
down. American households increasingly shoulder the burden
of financing higher education. This private financing of higher
education requires a growing share of household consump-
tion and investment spending, drawing resources away from
other sectors such as housing and other markets for consumer
finance. Most students today meet the growing cost by tak-
ing on debt. As a result of the shifting financial responsibility
for higher education, student debt is at record highs. College
graduates begin their careers with debt payments that absorb
income and supplant other important early-adulthood invest-
ment opportunities. Moreover, the increasingly private respon-
sibility for financing higher education diverts attention from
the important social benefits of an educated population as eco-
nomic decisions focus more and more on individual returns.
Thus, the debt-based system of higher education finance comes
at a larger cost: student debt limits the economic opportunities
of today’s young people, depletes other forms of consumer and
investment spending in the economy, and undermines the com-
monly shared gains that derive from an educated workforce and
citizenry.
Social Investment in Higher Education
The individual benefits of a college degree are widely acknowl-
edged, but the increasing focus on individual financing has
largely neglected similar calculations on the social scale. The
returns to individuals accrue in terms of employment oppor-
tunities and lifetime earnings. Comparing workers with a
bachelor’s degree to those whose education ended with a high
school diploma shows that a postsecondary credential is more
and more valuable, leading college graduates to higher life-
time incomes and lower unemployment rates relative to those
without a degree (Vandenbroucke 2015). However, mounting
economic evidence suggests the labor market is increasingly
credentialized, and hence persistent higher education wage gaps
reflect worsening outcomes for those without degrees—thus the
growing imperative of obtaining a higher education credential,
even as the costs are shifted to individual students.
These benefits, combined with wider opportunities in both
the labor market and the higher education system for women
and people of color, have driven rates of college attainment
among adults in the United States from less than one in ten 50
years ago to a record high of approximately one in three today
(US Census Bureau, Table A-2). Similarly, higher education is a
valuable social investment, with positive spillover effects from
generating new knowledge and expanding skills at both local
and national levels. The higher incomes associated with a col-
lege degree represent greater productive capacity and a higher
value of human capital stock economy-wide. These direct and
often clearly monetized gains accrue in terms of skills, income,
and increased productivity that contribute to GDP growth and
rising living standards for the entire economy.
Recent research from the Organisation for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD 2015) shows that the
social benefits of public spending on higher education far out-
weigh the public costs. In the United States, lower unemploy-
ment rates, higher tax revenues, and other social contributions
associated with educated workers result in net social benefits
worth between two and five times the dollar amount of public
spending on higher education. Yet even these impressive figures
capture only part of the gains. Research shows that better-edu-
cated people live longer, healthier lives, commit fewer crimes,
and are more civically engaged (OECD 2015). Higher educa-
tion plays a key role in our nations socioeconomic mobility
and, as a result, access to higher education is a crucial facet of
equality of opportunity for young people and families hoping
to achieve a better life. Finally, an increasingly productive and
highly educated society yields intergenerational advantages, as
the associated institutions, networks, and aptitudes are passed
down over time. Accounting for each of these benefits would
raise estimates of the reward for society beyond the OECD fig-
ures by reducing public expenditures on health care and crime,
improving quality of life, and contributing to equality of oppor-
tunity and political stability.
The social benefits of increasing educational attainment
are dispersed, generating returns even for those individuals who
choose to forego a college degree. These dispersed benefits in
10 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
the market for higher education are a classic example of posi-
tive externalities—benefits accruing as a result of exchange that
are not taken into account by private buyers and sellers. Like
other markets where positive externalities exist, the omission of
social benefits in individual cost/benefit calculations results in a
market failure. A higher education market composed of purely
private exchange would lead to conditions of chronic underin-
vestment. The key to avoiding a market failure and capturing
the social returns of an educated population is public support.
The United States has a history of financing higher education in
partnership with students and their families, with the majority
of college students attending public institutions supported by
state and federal spending (NCES 2015, Table 303.7). Yet over
recent decades that partnership has devolved and individuals
are taking on a growing share of the cost of higher education.
The rising individual cost burden of attaining a college
degree also has spillover effects on the rest of the economy.
With declining state support and a persistent social and eco-
nomic demand for college credentials, postsecondary educa-
tion is increasingly financed through debt. This debt weighs on
household finances, affecting the consumption and investment
opportunities of borrowers, with ripple effects across other con-
sumer debt markets and beyond. Debt service payments reduce
disposable income and consumption spending. College gradu-
ates focused on paying down debt are putting off other invest-
ments, like buying a home or starting a family—or taking on
yet more debt to obtain graduate degrees that are increasingly
necessary as the labor market credentializes. And as the indi-
vidual investment perspective drives a greater share of the mar-
ket, society risks losing valuable benefits to a higher education
market failure.
The current state of student debt
More than ever before, Americans recognize higher education
as an important milestone on the pathway toward prosperity
and financial stability. As a result, waning public support for
higher education and rising individual costs have prompted
the growth of student debt to record levels. According to the
Federal Reserve (2016), outstanding student loan debt totaled
$1.35 trillion as of the first quarter of 2016—an amount 28 per-
cent greater than all motor vehicle loans and 40 percent greater
than the value of outstanding student loan debt just five years
ago. The vast majority of this debt originates from federal lend-
ing, with the private student loan market accounting for just
7.6 percent ($99.7 million) of all student debt (MeasureOne
2015). The growth in borrowing occurred as more college stu-
dents turned to loans to finance their education and the typi-
cal loan amount per borrower increased (see Figure 1.1). In the
1989–90 academic year, 50.5 percent of undergraduate seniors
ages 18–24 relied on student loans for some portion of their
college costs. The average loan amount among those borrow-
ing was $15,200. At the end of the 2011–12 academic year, 68
Average Loan Balance $26,300
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90
100
1989–90
1999–2000
2011–12
Students Who Received Student Loans
Students Who Never Received Student Loans
Figure 1.1 Percentage of Undergraduate Seniors Who
Re
ceived Student Loans
Source: NCES 2014 Digest of Education Statistics, Ta ble 331.95
Average Loan Balance $22,100
Average Loan Balance $15,200
Percent
Share Cumulative
Borrowing Borrowing
Total 69% $29,384
Race/Ethnicity (with multiple)
White 67.5% $29,065
Black or African American 84.2% $33,015
Hispanic or Latino 71.9% $29,517
Asian American 47.2% $23,135
American Indian or Alaska Native 61.5%
Native Hawaiian/Other Pacific Islander
Other 81.0% $28,052
More Than One Race
Institution Type
Public Four-Year 64.1% $25,458
Private Not-for-Profit Four-Year 73.1% $32,388
Public Two-Year
Private For-Profit 87.2% $40,025
Others/Attended More Than One School 71.8% $29,444
Table 1.1 Share Borrowing and Cumulative Amount
Borrowed for Undergraduate Education among Those
with Debt, by Race/Ethnicity and by Institution Type for
Graduating Seniors, 2011–12
‡ Reporting standards not met.
Source: NCES 2011–12 National Postsecondary Student Aid Study (NPSAS:12)
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 11
percent of graduating seniors left college with some student
debt and the average balance rose to over $26,000 (NCES 2014,
Table 331.95). The growing reliance on student loans marks an
important generational shift as today’s graduates begin their
working lives hampered by debt payments that preclude other
economic opportunities.
Today the majority of college students incur student debt,
but the degree of exposure differs by critical demographic fac-
tors such as race and ethnicity and the type of academic institu-
tion attended (Table 1.1). Students at public institutions were
less likely to borrow than those at private for-profit or not-for-
profit institutions, but even at public schools most students
relied on loans to some extent (NCES 2013). Black and Latino
students are the most likely to take out loans and borrow greater
amounts. In 2011–12, 84 percent of black graduating seniors
had borrowed for college, as had 72 percent of Latinos, 68 per-
cent of whites, and 48 percent of Asian Americans (NCES 2013).
Black and Latino graduates, whose household finances are
already affected by racial gaps in wealth, income, and employ-
ment—even with a college degree—encounter a dispropor-
tionate burden as debt payments after graduation constitute a
larger portion of household budgets.
3
Recent research from the
Mapping Student Debt project (Steinbaum and Vaghul 2015)
shows that even below-average student loan balances can be
problematic for low-income borrowers choosing between mak-
ing on-time payments and other financial demands. And zip
codes with high minority populations are significantly more
likely to be burdened by their student debt payments (as a per-
centage of their income), and thus to go delinquent on their
loans.
The growth in student loan debt is driven by several impor-
tant factors, including a rapid rise in the cost of attaining a
degree (Figure 1.2) at the same time a college education became
increasingly associated with individual advancement and eco-
nomic success. After remaining relatively stable for decades,
average tuition and fees at public, undergraduate, four-year
institutions rose 156 percent between the 1990–91 and 2014–15
academic years. The total price tag, including tuition, fees, and
room and board, doubled over the period to reach $18,632 in
2014–15 (NCES 2015, Table 330.10).
The impact of this growth in the cost of college was magni-
fied by a protracted period of earnings stagnation for the typical
American household (Figure 1.3). According to the US Census
Bureau, real median household income was just 2 percent higher
in 2014 than it was in 1990 (US Census Bureau, Table H-9). The
rising cost of attendance over this period required college stu-
dents and their families to devote a growing portion of house-
hold budgets to higher education (Figure 1.4). In 1990, before
the rapid escalation of the college price tag, average tuition and
fees amounted to 6.3 percent of median household income,
17.6 percent when room and board are included. In 2014, aver-
age tuition and fees for one year of college would require 15.9
$0
$2,000
$4,000
$6,000
$8,000
$10,000
$12,000
$14,000
$16,000
$18,000
$20,000
1963–64
1965–66
1967–68
1969–70
1971–72
1973–74
1975–76
1977–78
1979–80
1981–82
1983–84
1985–86
1987–88
1989–90
1991–92
1993–94
1995–96
1997–98
1999–2000
2001–02
2003–04
2005–06
2007–08
2009–10
2011–12
2013–14
Tuition, Fees, Room and Board
Tuition and Fees
Sour
ce: NCES 2015 Digest of Education Statistics, Table 330.10
Figure 1.2
Cost of Full-Time Attendance at Four-Year Public Institutions (2014–15 dollars)
12 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
percent of the median household income, or 34.7 percent with
the inclusion of room and board (NCES 2015, Table 330.10; US
Census Bureau, Table H-9; authors’ calculation). For families
across the income distribution seeking a college credential, the
much faster growth of college costs than household incomes
over this period made debt an essential resource.
One major cause of the increases in the price of college and
incidence and amount of student debt over this period was the
decline in public funding as a share of the cost of education.
Although not the sole source of rising prices, analysis from the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York (among others) finds that
decreases in state and local higher education appropriations are
associated with net tuition increases, especially since the 2008–
09 recession (Chakrabarti, Mabutas, and Zafar 2012). According
to the State Higher Education Executive Officers Association
(SHEEO), which tracks the contributions of public funding,
tuition payments, and other revenue sources in higher educa-
tion, real per-student funding last year was 15.3 percent lower
than in 2008 and 20 percent below its 1990 level (SHEEO 2015).
These decreases in public funding represent a significant shift in
higher education finance over recent decades. As public funds
receded in importance, tuition payments made up an increasing
share of revenues. In 1990, tuition accounted for 25 percent of
revenues at public institutions. In 2015, the share of revenues
drawn from tuition payments was 46.5 percent (SHEEO 2015).
These changes have made a college degree less affordable for
American families, contributing to the rise in student debt, and
have transformed public higher education from a social invest-
ment to an increasingly private one.
The social costs of student debt
Student loan debt today places a significantly higher burden on
household finances than ever before, with implications for the
entire economy. Many borrowers struggle to make payments
due to unemployment, low incomes, and competing financial
demands. The US Department of Education publishes default
rates for student loan borrowers who have failed to make pay-
ments for at least 270 days within the first three years after leav-
ing college. Among those whose loans entered repayment in
2012, 11.8 percent of borrowers have failed to meet their obli-
gations for at least nine months (US Department of Education
2017). The consequences of default can be severe. Once a loan
is delinquent for 90 days it is reported to credit rating agencies;
at the 270-day default threshold it is assigned to a collection
agency (US Department of Education 2016). For households in
debt, delinquency and damaged credit can make it impossible
to purchase a house, a car, or even a cell phone plan. For the gov-
ernment lender, default raises the administrative cost of student
loan programs and heightens risk.
Even borrowers who are current in their payments face
additional constraints as a result of the growing reliance on debt
to finance higher education. Households with student loan bal-
ances are less likely to own a home and, consequentially, exhibit
lower net worth than comparable households with no student
debt. According to recent research by the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System (Mezza et al. 2016), every 10 per-
cent rise in student loan debt reduces the homeownership rate
of borrowers by 1 to 2 percentage points in the first five years
after leaving school. When student loan borrowers do purchase
Figure 1.4 Average Tuition and Fees as a Share of Median
Household Income
Source: NCES 2015 Digest of Education Statistics, Table 330.10; US Census
Historical Income Tables H-9
0
10
20
30
40
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
Tuition and Fees as a Share of Median Income
Tuition, Fees, Room and Board as a Share of Median Income
Percent
Figure 1.3 Growth in Cost of College Attendance and
Me
dian Household Income (1990=1)
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Tuition and Fees, Indexed to 1990
Tuition, Fees, Room and Board, Indexed to 1990
Median Income, Indexed to 1990
Sour
ce: NCES 2015 Digest of Education Statistics, Table 330.10; US Census
H
istorical Income Ta bles H-9
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 13
homes, they build equity more slowly. Researchers at the
Washington University Center for Social Development (Elliot,
Grintstein-Weiss, and Nam 2013) find that the home equity of
student loan debtors amounts to just half that of nonborrow-
ers. Since home equity is a central wealth-building vehicle for
American households, the interaction between student debt
and homeownership in the short run can have long-run conse-
quences for borrowers and feedback effects on other markets as
consumption patterns respond to lower wealth.
The broader economic effects of high student debt burdens
also manifest across markets in the form of reductions in busi-
ness formation, greater household vulnerability to economic
shocks, and reduced consumption spending due to lower dis-
posable income. Research from the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia (Ambrose, Cordell, and Ma 2015) demonstrates
that relatively high student loan debt dampens business forma-
tion, with the strongest effects among the smallest firms. Small
business owners in particular tend to rely on personal credit as
a substantial portion of business financing, and student loan
debt reduces access to alternative forms of credit. The authors of
the Philadelphia Fed study deduce a direct negative relationship
between student loan debt levels and small business formation,
amounting to a 14 percent decline in new businesses in coun-
ties where student loan debts are highest. Student loan debt also
creates disproportionate exposure to economic downturns. A
study from the St. Louis Federal Reserve (Elliot and Nam 2013)
shows that during the most recent recession households with
student debt experienced greater reductions in net worth than
households with no student debt. According to the authors,
every $1 increase in student loan debt in 2007 was associated
with $0.87 less net worth in 2009. Finally, given that rising loan
payments drain households’ disposable incomes, student debt
potentially presents new headwinds in the economy. While
increasing household debt drove higher spending in the years
leading up to the 2008–09 recession, households deleveraged in
the wake of the crisis, resulting in a drag on the economy as
consumer spending lagged (Albuquerque and Krustev 2015).
During the period that households paid down other forms of
debt, student loans continued to grow (Brown et al. 2014). Since
consumer spending depends on both wealth and income—each
of which is affected by the presence of debt and debt service
obligations—soaring student loan debt can result in slower
growth in the economy overall.
The rising burden of college costs on household balance
sheets has been accompanied by new risks, including slow
growth, deepening vulnerability to economic shocks, and the
potential for a higher education market failure. Complete can-
cellation of outstanding student loans could undo many of
these negative effects. By reversing the drag imposed by $1.35
trillion in outstanding student loans, we expect a net stimu-
lus to the economy through housing markets, small business
formation, growth in consumer spending, and the feedback
effects these changes create. These directly measurable effects of
student debt cancellation would be complemented by unmea-
sured social benefits like greater social mobility and quality of
life. Based on this research, student debt cancellation presents a
significant economic opportunity not only for the households
burdened by debt but for the entire US economy.
The Distributional Consequences of Student Debt,
Student Debt Cancellation, and Debt-Free College
This report finds that cancelling all outstanding student loan
debt would modestly improve output and employment.
However, the main controversy over student debt generally and
debt cancellation in particular has not been its macroeconomic
impact, but rather the implications for people in different
income and wealth quantiles and the impact on inequality. The
controversy arises from the factual observation that among bor-
rowers, those with the largest amount of debt outstanding tend
to have the highest incomes, and those who spend the most on
college (and who therefore—so the story goes—have the most
to gain from the option of free college) come from the highest-
earning families.
These observations have been widely interpreted as discred-
iting the sorts of policies we model here. For example, Sandy
Baum (2016) of the Urban Institute writes “forgiving all student
debt is such a misguided idea that it is hard to know where to
begin…. Because households in the top quartile of the income
distribution owe a disproportionate amount of student debt,
they would reap a disproportionate amount of the benefits if
all education debt were forgiven. Jordan Weissmann (2016) of
Slate was even more strident: An especially half-baked idea for
dealing with Americas student debt burden has been bubbling
up from the far reaches of the political left lately: Washington, a
few well-meaning souls say, should just forgive all of the loans—
wipe the slate clean. He continues: The most important thing
to realize about student loans is that most borrowers don’t have
too much trouble handling it.
14 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
The widespread criticism of ambitious policies to address
the student debt crisis, based on their supposedly regressive
impact, is overdrawn. In some cases, it misinterprets the evi-
dence about who is most burdened by student debt and who
would benefit most from relief. In this section, we consider the
evidence about the distribution of debt and debt burdens in
the population and the evolution of those distributions over
time. Our main point is that, while the largest loan balances
are indeed held by comparatively high-earning households, the
extent to which student debt is held by the rich has diminished
significantly. Moreover, the argument that the distribution of
the burden of student debt has not, in fact, changed very much,
even as the total amount of debt outstanding has increased dra-
matically, fails to consider the significant changes in the popu-
lation of people with any student debt at all. These issues of
interpretation extend beyond accurately assessing the distribu-
tional impact of the policies we model—they point to larger
problems with the assumptions behind existing higher educa-
tion, student debt, and labor market policies. The student debt
crisis is one of several linked manifestations of those problems.
Others are wage stagnation, underemployment, and increasing
inequality of household wealth.
Student debt was once disproportionately associated with
graduate school and with relatively well-off households, in part
because it was possible to graduate from community college or
a four-year public institution with little or no debt, and in even
larger part because many people did not need to obtain any
higher education credentials in order to access the labor market.
What has happened in recent decades, and especially since the
mid-2000s, is a vast expansion of student borrowing, such that
the preponderant share of younger cohorts newly entering the
labor market carry student debt. This expansion is due in part
to much higher tuition, mostly thanks to state-level cutbacks in
funding for higher education, and in part because it is simply
far more difficult to access the labor market now without higher
education credentials. And that “credentialization, in turn, is
due to the underperformance of the labor market since 2000
and especially since the financial crisis and the Great Recession
that began in 2008. Since 2000, the most important federal labor
market policy has been the extension of student debt and the
encouragement of a larger share of the population to obtain
debt-financed higher education credentials, on the theory that
underemployment and stagnant wages were caused by a “skills
gap that could be remedied through debt-financed higher edu-
cation. The most obvious and acute effect of that policy was
the growth of the high-priced for-profit higher education sec-
tor, but it was also evident in rising enrollment across all types
of institutions, even as tuition rose. The “skills gap” was a false
diagnosis of the labor market’s problems, and hence the pre-
scription of more debt-financed credentials not only failed to
solve the problem, it also created its own problem in the form
of unsustainable debt.
The distribution of student debt and debt burden in the
cross section
The total amount of student debt outstanding is dispropor-
tionately held by those in the top income quintile. Looney and
Yannelis (2015) report that just over a third of all outstanding
debt is held by the top 20 percent, as defined either by labor
market earnings from the Current Population Survey or by total
taxable income as reported in tax return data.
4
By contrast, only
13 percent of debt is held by the lowest quintile as determined
by labor market earnings, or 15 percent as determined by tax-
able income. Thus, debt outstanding is more skewed toward
the rich than is the distribution of the number of borrowers:
25 percent of federal borrowers were in the top quintile. The
reason for that is simply that the borrowers with the largest bal-
ances have a disproportionate share of the debt: a total of 62
percent of all outstanding debt is held by the top quintile of
the distribution of borrowers (as opposed to the distribution
of income). The borrowers with the largest balances have the
majority of total debt, and they are largely also drawn from the
richest households. These findings are the basis for the claim
that student debt cancellation would be regressive.
One thing that is not directly reported in the Looney and
Yannelis data is the distribution of income among quintiles of
the student debt distribution. According to the authors’ calcula-
tions, it appears that the top quintile of indebted households by
either labor market earnings or total taxable income earns at
minimum 50 percent of the total earnings/taxable income
5
which is greater than their share of debt (between 33 and 36
percent). This means that the richest households have lower
total debt-to-income ratios than households in the middle or
bottom of the distribution, even if they do have the highest debt
loads.
Looney and Yannelis do not report the distribution of
debt burdens”—meaning the student-debt-service-to-income
ratio—across households by income. Instead, they report
on the distribution of debt burdens for borrowers with debt,
regardless of their income. They find that the median burden
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 15
for borrowers two years after entering repayment in 2010 was 6
percent, a number that has not changed much over the length
of their sample (which, for the purpose of calculating debt
service, begins in 1999). Akers and Chingos (2014) similarly
compute the distribution of debt burdens from a different data
source, the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). According to
their analysis of the 2013 SCF, the median debt burden among
households headed by individuals aged 20–40 with any student
debt and positive labor market income was 4 percent, with a
16 percent debt burden being the cutoff for the 90th percentile.
In an unpublished analysis of credit reporting data linked
to American Community Survey outcomes at the zip code level,
Steinbaum and Vaghul (forthcoming) found that the burden of
student debt (meaning the ratio of debt service to income) is,
in general, inversely correlated with the average income of a zip
code. But that pattern obscures a slightly more nuanced geogra-
phy. The debt burden is highest in two types of zip codes: those
in historically disadvantaged areas, urban and rural, where both
incomes and absolute loan amounts are low; and those in rela-
tively high-earning urban areas disproportionately populated
by young cohorts with a large amount of student debt accumu-
lated and as-yet relatively low earnings given their credentials.
That pattern suggests that student debt is a problem of those
with low incomes relative to their credentials. It does not sug-
gest that those with credentials are necessarily financially secure.
The evolution of the distribution of student debt burdens
over time
One of the key findings motivating the argument that there is no
student debt crisis is that the distribution of student debt bur-
dens, conditional on having any student debt, has not changed
very much over time. The aforementioned study by Akers and
Chingos shows that the median payment-to-income ratio of
4 percent for 2013 has barely moved over successive waves of
the SCF. The right tail of that distribution has lengthened over
time: as reported above, the threshold for the 90th percentile of
households in their sample in 2013 is a debt burden of 16 per-
cent of income, whereas that threshold was 13 percent in 2007.
But it was much higher than that longer ago: 22 percent in 1998
and 20 percent in 1992. Akers and Chingos interpret these find-
ings to mean that borrowers are, on the whole, not significantly
more burdened by student debt now than they were in the past,
and hence there is little to worry about in the way of a student
debt crisis.
That is, quite simply, a misinterpretation of the data. The
set of households that has any student debt at all is quite differ-
ent now than it was a decade or two ago. Households that would
have appeared as “zeroes”—that is, not included—in the com-
putation of the student debt burden distributions in the 1990s
or the mid-2000s now enter those distributions with positive
values for their debt burdens. Akers and Chingos condition on
positive student debt to include households in their sample,
but if they had instead conditioned on a given level or range
of income or on a given educational attainment, they would
have found that the distribution of debt burdens had shifted
substantially to the right. In other words, to reach a given rung
on the “job ladder” that characterizes the labor market requires
more education credentials and therefore more student debt
now than it did in the past, while the earnings available on any
given rung have, for the most part, either stagnated or declined.
It may be the case that the median debt burden has not
changed very much even as the total amount of debt outstand-
ing has increased, but the median borrower has changed a great
deal. Whereas once debtors were likely to come from the ranks
of “traditional students”—that is, those attending either gradu-
ate school or private four-year institutions right after high
school, often with a family history of higher education and with
the family wealth to accompany it—recent student cohorts are
much more likely to be nontraditional students, often begin-
ning later in life and without a family background of college
attendance. This is exacerbated by rising costs associated with
the withdrawal of state support for higher education, which is
itself often regressive in the sense that the financially worst-off
institutions, which tend to serve nontraditional populations,
face the steepest budget cuts relative to enrollment and lack the
cushion of strong alumni support to fall back on. For all of those
reasons, student debt increasingly burdens a (growing) share of
the population that is ill-situated to carry and repay that debt.
An additional finding that highlights the growing burden
of student debt is the deteriorating repayment rates across
cohorts, especially following the Great Recession. Cohorts
entering repayment since 2011 are carrying more debt now than
they were in 2011 (Looney and Yannelis 2015). That means they
have made negative progress in absolute terms, and are nowhere
close to the benchmark of steady and full repayment over 10
years—thanks to low earnings, high delinquency rates, and a
labor market that demands ever-more credentials just to get
a job, necessitating more and more degrees and more debt. A
recent report by the National Center for Education Statistics
16 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
(Woo et al. 2017) found that repayment rates were worse and
delinquency rates much higher for the cohort of students who
entered college in 2003–04 compared to those who entered in
1995–96, and these disparities were particularly true of minor-
ity students, even those who completed their degrees. That dire
picture—which would in all likelihood appear even worse if it
included data on students who entered college during or after
the Great Recession—makes it hard to tell the old story that
going into debt to finance higher education is a route to the
middle class, and that the debt is easily affordable thanks to the
increased earnings graduates can expect.
What does the evolution of student debt tell us about the
labor market?
The country’s most significant labor market policy of the past
several decades is the growth of the federal student loan pro-
gram to finance higher education for a rising share of the pop-
ulation of entering cohorts across many types of institutions:
for-profit, two-year public, four-year public and private tradi-
tional undergraduate, and graduate school. The theory behind
that ambitious policy was that the labor market is characterized
by a “skills gap, whereby workers lack the skills necessary to
succeed in the global economy, and increasing higher education
attainment would close that gap.
6
Moreover, thanks to the higher
wages students could expect when they joined the labor market,
the beneficiaries of that expansion would be able to finance it
with student loans. The skills gap offered a conveniently unified
explanation both for earnings and wage stagnation overall and
for rising inequality in earnings among workers: those enjoying
large increases, so the story goes, were the ones with the skills
that positioned them to succeed in a changing and competitive
global economy.
The theory does not look very good in light of the student
debt crisis, as well as other labor market indicators: wage and
earnings stagnation even for workers with higher education
qualifications and the increasing credentialization that sees
workers with degrees take jobs that did not previously require
them (Clark, Joubert, and Maurel 2014). If the skills gap had
indeed been the problem, as student debt increased enormously
alongside degree attainment, so would have human capital,
and thus both aggregate earnings and the earnings of the newly
educated (who would not have gotten degrees had they been
part of earlier cohorts) would have increased. But, in fact, as
the share of the population with each level of credential has
increased—at the expense of the share with no credentials at
all—the effect has been to degrade the value of each credential
in terms of what jobs and earnings its holders can expect. The
result is a classic “rat race, in the sense that the only thing worse
than taking on burdensome debt in order to finance an increas-
ingly expensive credential that leads to worse outcomes than it
did previously is not doing so. That rat race only strengthens the
argument that the current policy of encouraging the expansion
of debt-financed higher education has been a failure, and there-
fore a radical departure is in order.
Many researchers who have investigated the student debt
crisis, and in particular the issue of delinquency on student
loans, agree that the weak labor market is the prime culprit
(Dynarski 2016; Muller and Yannelis 2017). But that does not
mean that higher education or student debt policy is not to
blame, because they are premised on the labor market value
of debt-financed higher education. Rising delinquency is one
manifestation of the failure of that premise, and the fact that
credentialed workers continue to take jobs at the expense of
those without credentials (who increasingly lack access to
employment opportunities at all) does not imply that continu-
ing or escalating the rat race is a sound policy. Yet that is what
is implied by continued insistence on the stability of the college
wage premium—thanks to deteriorating outcomes for those
without credentials—as justification for the status quo. On the
contrary: it is time to undertake a real labor market policy, and
to overcome squeamishness about acknowledging the failures
of the status quo. This includes acknowledging that student
debt accumulated to date might not be economically feasible
for debtors to carry and, eventually, pay off.
How does student debt interact with longstanding economic
disparities?
One inescapable conclusion from studying the incidence and
impact of student debt is that black and Hispanic borrowers
suffer disproportionately from its effect (Steinbaum and Vaghul
2016; Huelsman 2015a). Delinquency is highest in minority
neighborhoods and, for a given level of educational credential,
minority borrowers take on more debt and have more trouble
paying it off. The causes of that disparate impact are longstand-
ing racial disparities in both the credit and labor markets, house-
hold and family wealth far lower than white counterparts (even
for those making similar incomes), and segregation in higher
education itself, which clusters minority students in poorly
resourced institutions that are the least likely to lead to the
most valuable employment networks. The for-profit education
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 17
sector, where the most acute victims of the student debt crisis
are to be found, itself exists because more economic options are
often effectively closed off to nontraditional students, who are
likely to be minorities (McMillan Cottom 2017).
The pattern of racial disparity in student debt is especially
injurious because, as the engine of social mobility, higher edu-
cation is supposed to be the solution to disparities in back-
ground and family wealth. But what we are seeing now with the
student debt crisis repeats the themes that came to light during
the housing crisis and the Great Recession. Financing the pur-
chase of an asset with debt as a supposed mechanism of social
mobility is a facile policy for closing racial gaps when it fails to
account for disparities in access and quality. As with housing, so
with higher education: a mythology associated with its value as
an agent of social mobility gives rise to policies that encourage
borrowing to finance its acquisition. When the asset turns out
to be worth much less than promised, it is those who began at
the greatest disadvantage who are left holding the most burden-
some debts and who struggle to pay them off.
It is for this reason that a “public option for higher educa-
tion would be worth the most to the most disadvantaged stu-
dents (Huelsman 2015b). The supposedly egalitarian argument
against free or debt-free college is that those who currently
spend the most on higher education are those from the most
well-off backgrounds, and they would have the most to gain by
switching to the cheaper option. But that flies in the face of evi-
dence about the impact of universal public services: the rich do
not, generally, switch to them. Instead, it is those who lacked all
access before or who were forced to use substandard providers
who will benefit most from an affordable and universally acces-
sible option and the competitive pressure that puts on incum-
bent providers who had previously been able to benefit from a
captive, segmented market.
The real distributional impact of student debt cancellation
and free or debt-free college
The arguments against student debt cancellation and free or
debt-free college arising from their ostensibly inegalitarian
impact fail to account for the reality of the student debt crisis
and those who are its greatest victims. In this report, we show
that a radical policy for ending the student debt crisis could be
undertaken without doing economic harm—in fact, to moder-
ate macroeconomic benefit. That does not mean it is the only
possible solution, but there is no reason to constrain the policy
space based on outdated assumptions about the distribution
of student debt and its implications for both the underper-
formance of the labor market and for longstanding economic
disparities.
18 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Section 2: The Mechanics of
Student Debt Cancellation
This section will describe the mechanics of student debt cancel-
lation carried out by the federal government and the Federal
Reserve. As a basis for understanding and explaining the instru-
ments of debt relief, we first examine the current mechan-
ics of student debt and demonstrate balance sheet effects via
T-accounts throughout. T-accounts are tools that track changes
in assets (labeled A) and liabilities or equity (L/E) that result
from transactions or debt cancellations. It is important to keep
in mind, however, that the financial statement effects shown
and discussed here are not the same as the ultimate macroeco-
nomic effects that emerge from the policy. That is, the financial
statement effects shown in the T-accounts are the immediate
ones for the government, private investors, and student loan
borrowers. Additional effects—multiplier effects, as they are
often labeled—and feedback effects influencing the federal gov-
ernment’s budget position (as in so-called dynamic scoring”)
are by necessity omitted. These important but omitted dynamic
effects will be explicitly considered in Section 3, using large
macroeconometric models to simulate the debt cancellation.
There are two rationales for presenting these mechanics.
First, they present the direct effects of student debt cancellation
on government spending and revenue, household income and
net financial wealth, and private investors; these are the transac-
tions incorporated into the macroeconometric models in the
following section. Second, and most fundamentally, because
every transaction in the economy affects the financial state-
ments of those involved, knowing how financial statements are
affected is a basic prerequisite to fully comprehending the trans-
action itself (which is the key unit of analysis in the field of eco-
nomics). This final point also relates to the core concern of this
report, which is the macroeconomics of student debt cancella-
tion: while there are competing approaches to “accounting” for
the government’s cost of student loan programs (such as “fair
value”), for the purposes of understanding the macroeconomic
effects it is the impacts on financial statements of the various
sectors that are of interest.
The following analysis results in two key takeaways:
The cancellation of the Department of Educations loans will
result in an absolute increase in the national debt equal to the
debt service due on the securities previously issued to fund
these loans, not the amount of the loans themselves.
There is no “free lunch if the Federal Reserve carries out stu-
dent debt cancellation instead of the federal government. That
is, the direct effects upon the federal government’s immedi-
ate and future budget position would be essentially the same
whether the federal government or Federal Reserve carries
out the cancellation. As a later part of this section explains,
however, there are a few potential caveats to this conclusion,
involving what some might consider creative accounting on
the part of the Federal Reserve—though for several reasons
these accounting maneuvers would probably require changes
to current laws and are likely to be politically contentious.
The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation Carried
Out by the Government
Current servicing of student loans from a balance sheet
perspective
It is useful to first consider the effects of current student loan
repayment on the balance sheets of the borrowers, govern-
ment, and private owners of student loans. Table 2.1 shows the
financial statement effects of debt service on loans held by the
Department of Education (hereafter, ED) using T-accounts.
Table 2.1, as with all T-account tables in this section, shows
T-accounts for the federal government, Federal Reserve, banks,
student loan borrowers, and private investors. When borrowers
make a student loan payment, it reduces their deposits as the
payment is settled. Borrowers are assumed to be households, so
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Tsy Acct (p,i) -RBs (p,i) -RBs (p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -Loans (p)
-Loans (p) +Eq
Govt
(i) +Tsy Acct (p,i) -Eq
HH
(i)
Table 2.1 Balance Sheet Effects of Servicing of Student Loans Owned by Department of Education
Borrowers
Service ED
Loans
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 19
the reduction in the deposits of households is represented -D
HH
in the table. The payments also reduce the amount of outstand-
ing student loans (-Loans). In addition, because the payments
include an interest component, the payments and thus reduc-
tion in deposits are greater than the reduction in student loans,
reducing the borrowers equity (-Eq
HH
). On the banks’ balance
sheet, the banks settle the borrowers’ payment to the ED by
reducing the borrowers deposits (-D
HH
, which reduces bank
liabilities), while their own reserve balances held at the Fed are
debited (-RB, an offsetting reduction in assets). On the Federal
Reserves balance sheet, banks reserve balances (RBs) are deb-
ited while the Treasury’s account at the Fed is credited (+Tsy
Acct). On the federal government’s balance sheet, the credit to
the Treasury’s account (+Tsy Acct)—which would internally be
credited to the ED—reduces outstanding student loans (-Loans)
while the interest portion of the debt service payment raises the
net worth or equity of the federal government (+Eq
Govt
). Finally,
(p) refers to a payment of loan principal, or an entry of the same
size; (i) refers to the same for the interest portion of debt service
payments; and (p,i) refers to a payment of principal and inter-
est, or an entry of the same combined size. While the mechanics
are a bit complex due to the necessary inclusion of the banks
and the Fed, the net effect is to reduce student loans outstanding
while transferring deposits and net worth to the federal govern-
ment via the Treasury’s account at the Fed.
Changes in balance sheets for the servicing of student
loans held by the private sector are shown in Table 2.2. Here
the entries for the borrowers are the same as in Table 2.1. The
private investors will be credited with deposits (+D
PI
) by their
banks, which, as in Table 2.1, will be larger than the reduction
in loan principal, thereby raising equity (+Eq
PI
). Banks in the
aggregate simply debit the accounts of the borrowers and credit
the accounts of investors. (To avoid unnecessary complexity,
Table 2.2 abstracts from transfers of reserve balances between
the borrowers’ banks and the investors banks.) It is worth men-
tioning that while the servicing of student loans results in both
equity and deposits effectively being transferred from debtor to
creditor in both Tables 2.1 and 2.2, in the latter the transfers
are within the private sector and thus alter the distribution of
deposits and net worth within the sector, whereas in the for-
mer there is a reduction in the private sector’s total net worth as
well as a reduction in the total quantity of deposits (that is, the
“money supply”).
Possible methods of government-financed student debt
cancellation
Though there may be many details, the mechanics of debt can-
cellation are simple in general. The primary actions would be
the following:
The current portfolio of student loans held by the ED would
be cancelled or, equivalently, borrowers would simply be
allowed to stop making payments and any principal due on
a given date would be cancelled at that time (that is, the loan
would effectively be cancelled in stages as payments come
due). As of the second quarter of 2016, the ED’s outstanding
loans totaled $986.19 billion.
7
The federal government would either purchase and then can-
cel, or, equivalently, take over the payments on student debt
currently held by the private sector. As with the ED’s loans,
if the government purchases the privately held loans it can
choose to cancel them immediately or as borrowers payments
come due. The government-guaranteed loans are $266.69 bil-
lion, while nonguaranteed privately issued loans are $101.58
billion, both as of the second quarter of 2016. Having the gov-
ernment assume these payments or purchase and cancel the
loans is preferable to cancellation by private investors. The
latter would require the private sector to write down nearly
$370 billion in both assets and equity, which could be highly
destabilizing (or worse) for the affected sectors.
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-D
HH
(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -Loans (p) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
+D
PI
(p,i) -Eq
HH
(i) -Loans (p)
Table 2.2 Balance Sheet Effects of Servicing of Student Loans Owned by Private Investors
Borrowers
Service Private
Loans
20 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
The government cancels the Department of Educations loans
all at once
The ED’s loans were originally funded via sale of Treasury
securities.
8
The loan payments from student borrowers then in
theory enable the retirement of the securities, while the govern-
ment profits from the difference between the interest earned on
the ED’s loans less interest on the Treasury securities (though
there are some other considerations such as administrative
costs of the program and whether or not interest on the loans
is tax deductible for the borrowers). The balance sheet effects
are shown in Table 2.3. In the first transaction, the govern-
ment increases its liabilities (the Treasury securities, or +Tsys)
and receives payment for them into its account at the Fed when
private investors (not necessarily the same investors as in Table
2.2; at the margin these are Treasury dealers) have their bank
accounts debited while their banks have their reserve balances
debited. The loan reduces the Treasury’s account and adds back
reserve balances and deposits. The deposits are listed as belong-
ing to the academic institution (+D
UNI
for university” in this
case). The loan simultaneously raises the borrowers liabilities
and reduces net worth. Not shown here due to space constraints
is that the deposit would add to the net wealth of the academic
institution (ceteris paribus). While it is often the case that the
borrower receives some of the deposits—given that student loans
regularly cover expenses related to college, not just direct costs of
college itself (tuition, room and board, books, and so forth)—as
the borrower spends these funds, the end result will be a reduc-
tion in net wealth as the complementary entry to the loan. The
final entries present totals or net effects of the two transactions.
The cancellation of debt held by the ED is a concurrent
reduction in the federal government’s assets and its equity,
while it is simultaneously a reduction in debt and an increase
in equity for the debtors. This is shown in Table 2.4. Also, while
it reduces the government’s equity, the cancellation of publicly
owned student debt on its own does not increase the debt (i.e.,
liabilities) of the federal government. An increase in the federal
government’s debt can only result from issuing debt directly via
Treasury securities or similar means. For the student loan bor-
rowers, the cancellation reduces debt (the student loans) and
raises net worth, exactly offsetting the totals from Table 2.3.
When a loan is cancelled and equity reduced, an accom-
panying entry charges this reduction in equity to the income
statement, which thereby reduces profits. This reduction in
profits is a noncash charge that brings internal consistency for
the income statement and balance sheet. However, for the fed-
eral government, the income statement position is most often
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Tsy Acct(p) +Tsys(p) -RBs(p) -RBs(p) -D
PI
(p) -D
PI
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p) +Tsys(p)
-Tsy Acct(p) +RBs(p) +RBs(p) +D
UNI
(p) +Loans(p)
+Loans(p) -Tsy Acct(p) -Eq
HH
(p)
+Loans(p) +Tsys(p) -D
PI
(p) +Loans(p) -D
PI
(p)
+D
UNI
(p) -Eq
HH
(p) +Tsys(p)
Table 2.3 Treasury Issues Securities to Private Investors and Department of Education Lends to Student Borrowers
Government
Issues
Securities
ED Lends
to Student
Borrowers
Totals
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans (p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Loans (p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
Table 2.4 Cancellation of Student Loans Owned by Federal Government
ED Loans
Cancelled
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 21
presented in the context of the government’s budget surplus or
deficit, which is more of a cash flow measure that largely omits
such noncash charges in order to have consistency with the gov-
ernment’s issuing, repurchasing, or retiring of Treasury securi-
ties (that is, changes in the government’s liabilities). In the case
of cancelling the ED’s loans, the budgetary effects (and thus the
effects on the government’s outstanding liabilities) would be
incurred as debt service payments from borrowers that are not
received, reducing the government’s revenues relative to what
would have been projected and relative to expenditures.
However, this neglects a point that has significant implica-
tions: the absence of payments from borrowers is not in fact
a transaction but a counterfactual. Considering Tables 2.3 and
2.4 together in order to clarify, recall that the loans themselves
were originally funded by issuing Treasury securities and that
the borrowers’ payments were to have enabled the payment of
interest and retirement of principal on these securities. That is,
absent debt cancellation, the timing of the borrowers debt ser-
vice payments and the government’s payments to the security
holders were to have lined up for the most part. Therefore, the
deficits incurred each period that the borrowers debt service
is not received do not result in additional government liabili-
ties. Instead, the existing liabilities will be rolled over (that is,
a new security is issued to pay for the maturing one) and the
liabilities incurred when the loans were created simply become
permanent. In the sense that the governments liabilities were
projected to be reduced via student loans being paid down, the
cancellation results in additional government debt relative to
that baseline, but in terms of the absolute size of the govern-
ment’s outstanding liabilities, the cancellation of the ED’s loans
will result in no addition to the government’s liabilities, rela-
tive to a precancellation baseline (except for the amount of debt
service due).
The government cancels the Department of Educations loans
as borrowers’ payments come due
The conclusions reached regarding the effect of the cancella-
tion of the ED’s loans on the federal government’s outstanding
liabilities are more clearly shown by assuming the government
instead allows borrowers to cease payments and cancels the
loan principal due each period. In this scenario, it is easier to
illustrate the financial statement changes that would occur each
period and to then explain which of them are actual transac-
tions that occur as a result of cancellation and which result from
a comparison to projections without debt cancellation (that is,
are counterfactuals).
Table 2.5 presents the cancellation of principal owed on the
ED’s student loans each period. As the label indicates, the first
entry in Table 2.5 simply reverses the transaction in Table 2.1.
This is the counterfactual, which is not an actual transaction
but shows financial statement changes relative to the no-cancel-
lation scenario. The second entry is a transaction—the govern-
ment cancels the portion of the loan principal that would have
otherwise been due. This is much like the debt cancellation in
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Eq
Govt
(i) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Loans(p)
+Loans(p) -Tsy Acct(p,i) +Eq
HH
(i)
-Loans(p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
+Tsys(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
Table 2.5 Department of Education Loans Cancelled as Principal Comes Due—Relative to No Cancellation
REVERSE
Borrowers
Service
ED Loans
Government
Cancels
Principal Now
Due
Totals
Government
Issues
Securities
22 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Table 2.3, but in this case refers only to the principal due on
the specific date. The third entry shows the government issu-
ing new securities to offset the reduction in the government’s
budget position. The final row of entries presents the totals
or net of the two entries, which shows that the net effect is for
student loan borrowers to have more deposits and higher net
worth than is the case when they make debt service payments,
and for the federal government to have both reduced equity and
increased liabilities equal in size to the foregone principal and
interest payment. Another way of stating this is that student
loan borrowers now have an extra, say, $300 per month on aver-
age not debited from their bank accounts that becomes available
to spend, save, borrow against, or some combination of these,
relative to the no-cancellation scenario.
Because the first entry in Table 2.5 is a counterfactual, the
actual transactions are presented in Table 2.6. The first two trans-
actions are the same as the second and third entries in Table 2.5.
The significance of considering actual transactions is seen in the
combination of transactions two and three in Table 2.6. What
happens is government securities that would have been retired
by debt service payments are coming due. Absent the debt ser-
vice payments, the government instead issues new Treasury
securities to replace or roll over the previously issued securi-
ties. The payment due on Treasury securities is partly principal
and partly interest, so as the government issues new securities
to cover this payment, its liabilities increase by the amount of
interest due. (Note that the payment of interest on the Treasury
securities reduces the government’s equity and raises that of the
investors.) Therefore, the new securities issued will be in this
amount—that is, the national debt does in fact increase mod-
estly each year by the amount of interest due on the securities
issued when the loans were originated. Importantly, however,
the cancellation of the ED’s loans does not increase the national
debt by the value of the loans cancelled, but rather only by the
size of the interest payment due annually on the Treasury secu-
rities that financed the loans.
Government-led debt cancellation where the government
assumes payments on student loans issued by private investors
Unlike the ED’s loans, the government does not yet own these
private loans and thus would issue new Treasury securities
to purchase them. Financing the purchase and cancelling the
privately owned loans would be essentially simultaneous, and
therefore the changes to both the budget and liabilities of the
government would also be essentially simultaneous. As with
the ED’s loans, the government could also choose to cancel
debt service as it becomes due. A third option is for the govern-
ment to take over the borrowers’ debt service payments on these
loans, in which case the changes to the governments budget and
liabilities would be incurred over the rest of the lives of the loans
themselves. The discussion here begins with the latter option,
then turns to the former cases involving the governments pur-
chase of these loans.
Table 2.7 presents entries for the federal government’s
assumption of debt service on student loans owned by private
investors. In the first entry, as in Table 2.5’s counterfactual,
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans(p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p) -D
PI
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Tsys(p) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(i) -Tsy Acct(p,i) -Tsys(p)
-Loans(p) +Tsys(i) -Loans(p) +Tsys(i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p)
Table 2.6 Department of Education Loans Cancelled as Principal Comes Due—Actual Transactions
Government
Cancels
Principal Now
Due
Government
Issues
Securities
Government
Retires Securities
and Pays Interest
Totals
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 23
borrowers do not service their loans—this simply reverses all
transactions in Table 2.2. In the second entry, the government
makes the debt service payments, which debit its account at
the Fed and its equity by the principal and interest. This raises
reserve balances held by the Fed by the same amount as banks
then credit the deposits of the private investors. The loans are
assumed to still be liabilities of the borrowers (since the fed-
eral government did not purchase these loans), so the govern-
ment’s debt service payment reduces the principal of the loan
and raises the net worth of the borrowers by the same amount.
For this entry, the government’s net worth has fallen by the
value of the principal and interest; the borrowers’ net worth has
increased by the value of the principal payment; and the private
investors’ net worth has increased by the value of the interest
payments. In the third entry, the government issues securities
to cover the shortfall, just as in Tables 2.5 and 2.6. The sum or
net of these entries is an increase in household deposits and net
worth, both by the value of principal and interest; a decrease
in the government’s net worth of the same size, offset by an
increase in its liabilities; and the net for the private investors is
a purchase of the new Treasury securities (note that the private
investors holding the student loans are not assumed to be the
same investors purchasing the new Treasury securities). Table
2.7 also shows that, as a result of the cancellation, the borrowers
now have deposits and net worth they would not otherwise have
had, much like in Table 2.5.
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Loans(p) -D
PI
(p,i) -Eq
PI
(i)
-D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(i) +Loans(p)
-Tsy Acct (p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +DPI(p,i) -Loans(p) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Tsy Acct (p,i) +Eq
HH
(p) -Loans(p)
+Tsy Acct (p,i) +Tsys (p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
+Tsys (p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) +Tsys (p,i)
Table 2.7 Federal Government Assumes Debt Service on Privately Owned Student Loans—Relative to No Cancellation
REVERSE
Borrowers
Service
Private Loans
Government
Services Private
Loans
Totals
Government
Issues
Securities
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Tsy Acct (p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) -Loans(p) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Tsy Acct (p,i) +Eq
HH
(p) -Loans(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys (p,i) -RBs (p,i) -RBs (p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct (p,i) +Tsys (p,i)
+Tsys (p,i) -Loans(p) -Loans(p) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p) +Tsys(p,i)
Table 2.8 Federal Government Assumes Debt Service on Privately Owned Student Loans—Actual Transactions
Government
Services Private
Loans
Government
Issues
Securities
Totals
24 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
The actual transactions for the government’s assumption
of debt service payments for privately owned loans are in Table
2.8, which omits the reversal of borrowers’ debt service (from
Table 2.7). The totals row shows that the government has issued
liabilities as its net worth has fallen; student loan borrowers
have seen their loan principal fall and net worth rise in kind;
and private investors have had some loan principal paid off,
increased net worth by the amount of interest due in the period,
and purchased Treasury securities in the amount of principal
and interest (again, the investors holding the student loans are
not necessarily the same as those investing in Treasury securi-
ties). Note that the totals for the government are the same for
Tables 2.7 and 2.8. In other words, the counterfactual is not rel-
evant to the government’s position: the government’s liabilities
are increasing by the combined principal and interest payment,
both relative to no cancellation and in absolute terms. This is
also the core difference from the EDs loans, which only raise
the government’s liabilities in absolute terms by the amount of
interest due annually.
Government-led debt cancellation where the government
simultaneously purchases and then cancels loans owned by
private investors
As noted above, an alternative to assuming the debt service to
private investors is to have the federal government purchase
these loans from the private investors at the outset. Table 2.9
presents the T-accounts for transactions involved in this sce-
nario. The first transaction is the government issuing Treasury
securities that will replenish the Treasury’s account at the Fed
and enable the purchase of the private securities. The second
transaction is the purchase of the privately owned student
loans, which essentially reverses the entries from the first trans-
action, except that private investors have effectively swapped
student loans for Treasury securities. Table 2.9 assumes, for
simplicity, that the government acquires the loans from private
investors at their book value with no interest accrued since the
most recent payments from the borrowers (alternative assump-
tions for either of these would likely not have macroeconomic
significance and would not change the nature of the analysis
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Tsy Acct(p) +Tsys(p) -RBs(p) -RBs(p) -D
PI
(p) -D
PI
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p) +Tsys(p)
-Tsy Acct(p) +RBs(p) +RBs(p) +D
PI
(p) +D
PI
(p)
+Loans(p) -Tsy Acct(p) -Loans(p)
+Loans(p) +Tsys(p) +Tsys(p)
-Loans(p)
Table 2.9 Federal Government Purchases Privately Owned Student Loans
Government
Issues
Securities
Government
Purchases
Private Loans
Totals
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Loans(p) +Tsys(p) +Tsys(p)
-Loans(p)
-Loans(p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+Tsys(p) -Loans(p) +Tsys(p)
-Eq
Govt
(p) +Eq
HH
(p) -Loans(p)
Table 2.10 Federal Government Purchases and Cancels Privately Owned Student Loans
Totals
from
Table 2.9
Government
Cancels Private
Loans
Totals
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 25
here). The totals or net changes for Table 2.9 are simply swaps
of Treasury securities for privately owned student loans among
the federal government and private investors.
Table 2.10 adds the governments cancellation of the stu-
dent loans, which reduces the government’s equity while also
raising the equity of the student loan borrowers. An account-
ing difference between the government taking over the pay-
ments, as in the discussion above, and purchasing/cancelling
the loans here is that only the principal amounts show up in
the transactions. This is because the purchase and cancellation
occur essentially simultaneously, rather than over the remaining
life of the loans. However, this is simply a difference in timing
of the transactions, not in gross size of total transactions (of
macroeconomic significance). Having sold the loans, investors
can reinvest the proceeds from the sale to earn the interest they
would have earned on the loans (of course, interest rates on
the new investments could be different from those previously
earned on the student loans). Similarly, and as in the scenario in
which the government takes over debt service payments to pri-
vate investors, borrowers that have had their loans cancelled will
effectively have the foregone principal and interest payments as
additional income at the time debt service would have been due,
and thus additional deposits and equity relative to no cancella-
tion. From the government’s perspective, it is simply incurring
the deficits related to principal payments to private inves-
tors at the beginning rather than over the course of the loans’
maturities, and thus it is simply a difference between the present
value and future value of the loan cancellation. As with the ED’s
loans, the cancellation has eliminated its source of revenue to
service the Treasury securities issued in Table 2.9. The govern-
ment therefore will be issuing Treasury securities in the future
as it rolls over the portion of the outstanding liabilities that is
maturing and the liabilities effectively become permanent. As it
rolls these liabilities over, it will also increase its liabilities by an
amount equal to the debt service due on them.
Government-led debt cancellation where the government
purchases student loans issued by private investors and
cancels principal as payments come due
As with the ED’s loans, the process of rolling over principal from
the securities originally issued and then issuing new securities
to cover interest payments due is more straightforward in the
case in which the government purchases the privately owned
student loans and cancels principal as payments come due. In
Table 2.11, the first entry is the reversal of the debt service pay-
ments, or the counterfactual. The second entry is the cancel-
lation of the principal due. The third entry is the issuance of
Treasury securities, since the cancelled borrowers’ debt service is
not forthcoming to service the Treasury securities issued when
the government purchased the privately issued loans in Table
2.9. The total or net effect relative to the no-cancellation sce-
nario is that borrowers have additional deposits reflecting the
Table 2.11 Federal Government Purchases and Cancels Privately Owned Student Loans as Payments Come Due—Relative to
No Cancellation
REVERSE
Borrowers
Service
Private Loans
Owned by
Government
Government
Cancels
Principal Now
Due
Totals
Government
Issues
Securities
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Tsy Acct (p,i) -Eq
Govt
(i) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Loans(p)
+Loans(p) -Tsy Acct (p,i) +Eq
HH
(i)
-Loans(p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys (p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
+Tsys (p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) +Tsys (p,i)
26 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
increased net worth each period, private investors (which are
Treasury dealers, at the margin) have purchased Treasury secu-
rities, and the government’s reduced net worth and offsetting
additional liabilities are equal in amount to the foregone princi-
pal and interest for the period.
The actual, direct transactions are shown in Table 2.12. As
previously, the reversal of the student loan payment in Table
2.11 is not an actual transaction, even though the borrowers
do have more income due to reduced financial obligations for
the period relative to no cancellation. In Table 2.12, the govern-
ment cancels principal currently due, then issues securities for
the combined principal and interest foregone in order to retire
and pay interest on securities sold when the privately held loans
were purchased. As with the ED’s loans, the securities matur-
ing are equal in size to the principal payment, so the net issu-
ance of securities is equal to the interest portion. However, by
contrast with the cancellation of the ED’s loans—which were
already funded with the issuance of Treasuries when the loans
were created—the securities issued by the government to pur-
chase privately owned loans, as illustrated in Table 2.9, are a new
budgetary cost, relative to current deficit and debt levels.
Concluding remarks on government-led cancellation of
privately owned student loans
As with the ED’s loans, the difference between Tables 2.11 and
2.12 depends on whether one considers the cancellation in com-
parison to the no-cancellation scenario or in terms of actual
transactions. For the borrowers, the former is more useful, since
they will have additional income available that would otherwise
have been committed to the principal and interest payment.
For the government, the latter is more useful, since it purchased
the loans with the purpose of cancelling them. Therefore, it is
most appropriate to view the government’s purchase of pri-
vately owned student loans as raising its liabilities by the same
amount, while the foregone debt service after the principal is
cancelled (either at once or as it comes due) raises the govern-
ment’s liabilities annually by the amount of interest due on the
securities issued to purchase the loans.
Overall, aside from the timing of the government’s transac-
tions, there is no difference of macroeconomic significance for
those involved if the government purchases and then cancels the
loans, as Tables 2.9, 2.10, 2.11, and 2.12 present, or takes over
the responsibility for repaying the loans, as assumed earlier in
Table 2.8. The only issue of much note is whether to cancel the
loans immediately after purchasing them or as the borrowers
payments come due, but this is simply an issue of present value
of the loans compared to the future value. And in either case,
the government will essentially roll over the Treasury securities
issued to purchase the loans as the borrowers payments come
due, while adding to them new securities issued in the amount
of interest due annually.
Concluding remarks on government-led debt cancellation
The net financial effects of student debt cancellation for student
loan borrowers would be (1) an increase in net financial wealth,
and (2) an increase in after-tax income available to spend, save,
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans(p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys (p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Tsys(p) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(i) -Tsy Acct(p,i) -Tsys(p)
-Loans(p) +Tsys(i) -Loans(p) +Tsys(i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p)
Table 2.12 Federal Government Purchases and Cancels Privately Owned Student Loans as Payments Come Due—Actual
Transactions
Government
Cancels
Principal Now
Due
Government
Issues
Securities
Government
Retires Securities
and Pays Interest
Totals
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 27
or borrow against rather than commit to debt service. Further,
even if all of the loans remained liabilities for borrowers and
were only cancelled in small steps as each payment came due, it
would be reasonable for households to behave as if these loans
had been cancelled all at once—since, regardless of the timing
of the cancellation, households will find themselves with the
additional income that would have otherwise been used for
debt service. It is the same from the government’s perspective—
the timing of the effects on its budget position and rolling over
of liabilities is largely unaffected by the choice of whether to
cancel the loans outright or as payments come due. Finally, it
is also largely irrelevant for the government’s budget position
and liabilities whether it assumes debt service payments or pur-
chases the loans.
There is, however, a significant difference with respect to
the impact on the government’s liabilities between the cancel-
lation of the ED’s loans and the loans owned by private inves-
tors. For the former, because the liabilities have already been
issued in the past to make these loans, in absolute terms cancel-
lation results in new liabilities only in the amount of interest
due on the securities issued earlier; for the latter, however, new
liabilities will be incurred in order to purchase the loans. The
point of presenting tables for both the counterfactuals and the
actual transactions is that there is a large difference, which has
substantial political significance, between the actual increase
in the government’s liabilities that results from cancellation of
the ED’s loans and the increase relative to the no-cancellation
scenario (which scenario/table is more relevant depends on the
question being asked). Particularly in an environment of very
low interest rates, the interest due on $1.1 trillion in govern-
ment securities may be as low as $10 billion to $30 billion per
year (depending on maturity of securities issued and time of
issuance), which is obviously much different than incurring the
entire $1.1 trillion in cancelled loans (plus interest) as new gov-
ernment liabilities.
The Mechanics of Student Debt Cancellation Carried
Out by the Federal Reserve
This section will discuss debt cancellation carried out by the
Fed, rather than by the government, since some advocates have
argued in favor of this approach. The primary rationale for sug-
gesting the Fed carry out the cancellation appears to be a belief
that there may be a “free lunch in the sense that the govern-
ment’s budget position does not need to be affected. As this
section will demonstrate, that is probably not the case. The dis-
cussion here will consider the same scenarios as those in which
the federal government carries out the debt cancellation. The
core takeaway from this section is that there is no macroeco-
nomically significant difference for the federal government’s
budget position and liabilities issued (that is, the national debt)
if the Fed carries out the debt cancellation rather than the fed-
eral government.
The Federal Reserve purchases the Department of
Educations loans
Since the ED loans are not marketable, an act of Congress would
appear necessary if it is not legally permissible for the ED to
sell the loans to the Fed. Even if it is permissible, congressional
action could be necessary if the Fed were unwilling to take such
action on its own (particularly given the ultimate purpose of
cancelling the loans). Once the Fed acquires the loans, it credits
the Treasury’s account at the Fed for the same amount. A rea-
sonable assumption—though not necessary in terms of macro-
economic significance—is that the Fed would acquire the loans
at their current value. In this case, the transaction is a simple
transfer of loans and balances between the federal government
and its central bank. This is shown in Table 2.13. As the current
value of student loans held by the ED is near $1 trillion, the
Treasury now has this much added to its account. The federal
government is therefore essentially $1 trillion further under the
national debt ceiling than it was prior to the Fed’s acquisition of
the student loans.
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Tsy Acct (p) +Loans (p)
+Tsy Acct (p)
-Loans
(p)
Table 2.13 Federal Reserve Acquires Loans Owned by Department of Education
Fed Buys Loans
from
ED
28 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Some fundamentals of the Federal Reserve’s remittances and
their relevance to student loan cancellation
To understand the mechanics of the Fed carrying out student
loan cancellation, it is useful to consider first what happens if
the Fed owns loans but instead does not cancel them and simply
collects payments as they become due. This is shown in Table
2.14. As borrowers pay debt service, their debt and deposits fall,
but so does their net worth, due to the additional interest cost of
the debt service. The borrowers banks simply debit the deposit
accounts of the borrowers while their own reserve accounts are
debited in kind. The loans owned by the Fed are debited by the
amount of principal paid down. Due to the interest portion of
the debt service payment, the quantity of reserve balances deb-
ited is greater than the reduction in the student loan principal,
thereby raising the Fed’s equity.
The portion of the Fed’s equity that has increased is called
“surplus capital, to distinguish it from the “paid-in capital”
contributed by member banks. The Fed’s additions to surplus
capital—profits after costs and dividend payments to member
banks on their paid-in capital—were capped by law at $10 bil-
lion by the 2015 Fixing America’s Surface Transportation Act
(FAST Act), which amended the Federal Reserve Act to require
that any capital surplus greater than this amount be transferred
to the Treasury.
9
The Fed’s “surplus capital” account is much
like a corporations retained earnings” account on its balance
sheet; therefore, the Fed is essentially limited to cumulative
retained earnings of $10 billion. In January 2016, for instance,
the Fed transferred $98 billion of what would otherwise have
been added to the capital surplus, or “retained earnings, to the
Treasury’s account, as well as another $19 billion that had been
accumulated beyond the $10 billion statutory limit prior to the
imposition of the new cap.
10
The transfer from the Fed’s surplus capital to the Treasury’s
account is shown in Table 2.15. The first entry repeats Table
2.14. In the second entry, the Treasury’s account is credited for
the interest payments as a result of the Fed’s transfer of its addi-
tional capital surplus to the Treasury’s account. The total or net
effect is that the profits from the loan are now added to the gov-
ernment’s budget position, while the Fed is returned to a posi-
tion in which its equity is unchanged.
The Federal Reserve cancels the Department of Educations
loans all at once
Turning to the cancellation, now assume all of the ED loans
are cancelled. In Table 2.16, the first entry is the Fed’s purchase
of the loans from the ED. The second entry is the cancellation.
This is not the end though, because the reduced Fed equity
position will be transferred to the Treasury over time as the Fed
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans(p) -RBs(p,i) -RBs (p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -Loans(p)
+Eq
Fed
(i) -Eq
HH
(i)
Table 2.14 Borrowers Service Student Loans Owned by Federal Reserve
Borrowers
Service Loans
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans(p) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -Loans(p)
+Eq
Fed
(i) -Eq
HH
(i)
+Tsy Acct(i) +Eq
Govt
(i) +Tsy Acct(i)
-Eq
Fed
(i)
+Tsy Acct(i) +Eq
Govt
(i) -Loans(p) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -D
HH
(p,i) -Loans(p)
+Tsy Acct(i) -Eq
HH
(i)
Table 2.15 Transfer from Federal Reserve’s Surplus Capital Account to Treasury’s Account
Borrowers
Service Loans
Fed
Remittances to
Government
Totals
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 29
waits until it accumulates enough profits—which would likely
require several years, if not a decade or more—for its surplus
capital to return to $10 billion. Thereafter, the Fed’s profits
send its surplus capital above $10 billion, at which time the Fed
finally has profits to remit to the Treasury as in Table 2.16.
The core point here is that there is no budgetary “free
lunch available to the federal government if the Fed carries out
the loan cancellation. Whether the Fed or the government can-
cels the EDs loans, the loss will be incurred by the government.
A minor difference would be that the losses would follow the
pattern of the Fed’s profits. In the case of the government car-
rying out the cancellation, it is the path of principal and interest
payments on the Treasuries issued (in order for the ED to lend
to student borrowers) that determines the annual effects on the
government’s budget position and the securities that are then
issued to roll over the principal and interest payments.
The Federal Reserve cancels debt service payments for the
Department of Educations loans
As with the government carrying out the cancellation, interac-
tions between the Fed and the Treasury’s account are easier to
present in the case where student debt is cancelled as payments
come due. Table 2.17 presents this scenario relative to no can-
cellation. In the first row of Table 2.17, households’ deposits
increase by the principal and interest, while their loan liability
and equity increase by principal and interest due. For the Fed,
this raises the loan principal and reserve balances but reduces
surplus capital by the accrued interest. When borrowers loan
principal coming due is cancelled in the second entry, their
equity or net worth rises in kind. For the Fed, loan principal
falls and reduces equity in kind. The totals show that household
deposits and equity have risen by the amount of the principal
and interest due, the Fed’s equity has fallen by the same amount,
and bank reserve balances have risen.
The fall in the Fed’s equity, booked as a reduction in sur-
plus capital, then reduces the Fed’s remittances to the federal
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Tsy Acct (p) +Loans (p) +Tsy Acct (p)
-Loans (p)
-Loans(p) -Eq
Fed
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
Table 2.16 Federal Reserve Cancels Loans Purchased from Department of Education
Fed Buys
Loans from ED
Fed Cancels
Loans
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Loans(p) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Loans(p)
-Eq
Fed
(i) +Eq
HH
(i)
-Loans (p) -Eq
Fed
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i)
-Eq
Fed
(p,i)
Table 2.17 Federal Reserve Cancels Debt Service Payments for Department of Education Loans—Relative to No Cancellation
REVERSE
Borrowers
Service Loans
Fed Cancels
Loan Principal
Now Due
Totals
30 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
government by the same amount. Therefore, the cancellation
of the student loan payments raises the government’s budget
deficit by the same amount relative to no cancellation, which is
shown in Table 2.18. The first entry is the totals row from Table
2.17. The second is the reduction in remittances. The totals for
Table 2.18 show that the Treasury’s account and equity—and
thus the federal government’s budget position—have been
reduced by the foregone principal and interest.
Whether the fall in the Treasury’s account in Table 2.18
results in the Treasury issuing new securities depends on what
the government does with credits to its account from Table 2.16.
While the additional balances might appear to enable the gov-
ernment to “print money” rather than spend via tax revenues or
issuing Treasuries, the balances credited in Table 2.16 are instead
already “spoken for, since they will offset reduced remittances
from the Fed cancelling student debt service payments.
Nonetheless, the government can choose to use the bal-
ances credited to its account in Table 2.16 to either offset
subsequent remittance reductions or retire previously issued
securities. Again, one might consider the latter choice equiva-
lent to “monetizing the debt, but the budgetary consequences
of the two choices are essentially the same. Table 2.19 shows the
government retiring Treasury securities after the Fed purchases
the ED’s loans. The first entry is the same as in Table 2.16. In the
second entry, the retirement of securities raises the Fed’s reserve
balances in kind. The totals show that while the government has
used the loan proceeds to retire liabilities incurred when the ED
made the loans, the reserve balances remain.
As explained in Appendix C in the digression on the Fed’s
daily operations in the federal funds market, for the Fed to
achieve its interest rate target in the presence of such a large
increase in the supply of reserve balances requires it to pay inter-
est on the reserve balances (IOR) at its target rate to banks (see
Figure C.3 in Appendix C). But IOR payments to banks reduce
Fed profits and then reduce Fed remittances, leaving the govern-
ment bearing the cost of IOR at roughly the same magnitude as
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Tsy Acct(p) +Loans(p) +Tsy Acct(p)
-Loans(p)
-Tsy Acct(p) -Tsys(p) +RBs(p) +RBs(p) +D
PI
(p) +D
PI
(p)
-Tsy Acct(p) -Tsys(p)
-Loans(p) -Tsys(p) +Loans(p) +RBs(p) +RBs(p) +D
PI
(p) +D
PI
(p)
-Tsys(p)
Table 2.19 Federal Government Retires Securities Using Funds from Sale of Loans to Fed
Fed Buys
Loans
from ED
Treasury
Retires
Securities
Totals
Table 2.18 Federal Reserve Reduces Remittances to Treasury—Relative to No Cancellation
Totals
from
Table 2.17
Fed
Reduces
Remittances
Totals
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i)
-Eq
Fed
(p,i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) -Tsy Acct(p,i)
+Eq
Fed
(p,i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i)
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 31
it would bear the cost of interest on the securities if it did not
retire them. In other words, whether or not the government uses
the credits in Table 2.19 to retire securities, its budget position
will be impacted as if it did not retire them.
Overall, as the Fed passes the cost of cancelled student debt
payments to the government via reduced remittances, the gov-
ernment will either draw down its account at the Fed, as in Table
2.18, or issue new securities that effectively replace those retired
in Table 2.19. The net impact on the government’s budget posi-
tion relative to no cancellation is thus unaltered by whether the
Fed or the government cancels the ED’s loans.
Table 2.20 shows the actual transactions for the Fed cancel-
ling student debt service payments. The first two transactions
are the second entries for Tables 2.17 and 2.18, respectively. For
simplicity, Table 2.20 assumes that the government keeps the
balances credited to its account in Table 2.16 instead of retiring
securities. In the third and fourth transactions, therefore, the
government rolls over the securities issued when the ED made
its loans, resulting in a net issuance of new securities that covers
interest due. In the totals, credits to the Treasury’s account in
Table 2.16 fall by the cancelled principal payments. This repeats
each period until all principal payments are cancelled and all
balances credited in Table 2.16 are debited.
Instead of issuing new securities to make the interest pay-
ments, in Table 2.20 the government of course could debit the
balances credited in Table 2.16. But this would add reserve
balances, resulting in IOR payments to banks ultimately borne
by the government via reduced remittances.
Overall, in Table 2.20 there is again no financial benefit to the
government if the Fed purchases the ED’s loans and cancels them.
The Federal Reserve assumes debt service payments for loans
owned by private investors
If the Fed assumes debt service payments on loans owned by
private investors, it will be making direct principal and inter-
est payments to the investors on behalf of a third party. This
will directly reduce the Fed’s profits and thus its equity. As in
the case of the ED’s loans, it is expected that an act of Congress
would be required for the Fed to take over the debt service pay-
ments on privately owned loans or purchase the loans and then
cancel them.
The transactions are shown relative to no cancellation for
this scenario in Table 2.21. The first entry is the counterfac-
tual in which borrowers do not service the loans. In the second
entry, the Fed services the loans by creating reserve balances that
then result in the private investors’ banks crediting their deposit
accounts. In the third entry, the Fed reduces remittances by the
amount of the fall in its equity for the period, which reduces the
government’s budget position by the same amount. The fourth
entry is the government issuing securities in response to the
budget shortfall. The totals here are the same as when the govern-
ment assumed these debt service payments in Table 2.7; while
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans (p) -Eq
Fed
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
-Tsy Acct(p) -Eq
Govt
(p) -Tsy Acct(p)
+Eq
Fed
(p)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Tsys(p) +RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(i) -Tsy Acct(p,i) -Tsys(p)
-Tsy Acct(p) +Tsys(i) -Loans(p) -Tsy Acct(p) -Loans(p) +Tsys(i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p)
Table 2.20 Federal Reserve Cancels Debt Service Payments for Department of Education Loans—Actual Transactions
Fed Cancels
Loan Principal
Now Due
Fed Reduces
Remittances
Government
Issues
Securities
Govt Retires
Securities and
Pays Interest
Totals
32 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
the Fed is making the payments, the ultimate effects impact the
government’s budget position and its liabilities, not the Fed’s.
The actual transactions are in Table 2.22. As in Table 2.8
where the government assumed the payments, the totals for the
government are the same in Tables 2.21 and 2.22. Table 2.22
simply shows that the private investors will receive their pay-
ments, while the households will have their principal cancelled.
Table 2.21, by contrast, shows that, relative to no cancellation,
there is no difference for the private investors (they receive their
payments regardless), while the households have both principal
and interest available as additional disposable income.
The Federal Reserve purchases and cancels loans owned by
private investors
Table 2.23 shows the T-accounts for the Fed’s purchase and
cancellation of the privately owned student loans. Here again,
as a simplifying assumption, the Fed is purchasing the student
loans at the current value, thereby not affecting the equity of the
private investors.
11
Because the cancellation reduces the Fed’s
equity by the amount of the loans, the Fed will reduce its annual
remittances until they sum to this amount. This will reduce the
government’s budget position annually, requiring the govern-
ment to issue and pay interest on new securities of the same
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Loans(p) -D
PI
(p,i) -Eq
PI
(i)
-D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(i) +Loans(p)
+RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) -Loans(p) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Fed
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p) -Loans(p)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) -Tsy Acct(p,i)
+Eq
Fed
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
+Tsys(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +D
HH
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
Table 2.21 Federal Reserve Assumes Debt Service on Privately Owned Student Loans—Relative to No Cancellation
REVERSE
Borrowers
Service Private
Loans
Fed Services
Private Loans
Fed Reduces
Remittances
Government
Issues
Securities
Totals
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+RBs(p,i) +RBs(p,i) +D
PI
(p,i) -Loans(p) +D
PI
(p,i) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Fed
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p) -Loans(p)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) -Tsy Acct(p,i)
+Eq
Fed
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
+Tsys(p,i) -Loans(p) -Loans(p) +Eq
PI
(i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) +Eq
HH
(p) +Tsys(p,i)
Table 2.22 Federal Reserve Assumes Debt Service on Privately Owned Student Loans—Actual Transactions
Fed Services
Private Loans
Fed Reduces
Remittances
Government
Issues
Securities
Totals
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 33
annual amount to cover the reduced remittances. As with the
Fed cancelling the ED’s loans all at once, the timing of the bud-
getary impacts will match the remittance shortfall rather than
the path of debt service payments foregone.
Because the reserve balances the Fed used to purchase the
private loans are left circulating, the Fed will have to pay IOR
on them at its target rate. These IOR costs of the Fed will be
borne by the government as the Fed’s remittances fall. Then,
while the Fed’s remittances fall until the total value of the loans
has been accounted for, the government will be issuing addi-
tional Treasury securities that will, over time, effectively replace
the reserve balances. Thus, whether the Fed purchases the loans
with new reserve balances or the government does it by issuing
new securities, the government will bear the interest costs of
financing the purchase.
The Federal Reserve purchases loans owned by private
investors and cancels debt service payments
As with the government carrying out the cancellation, the
results discussed for the Fed purchasing and then cancelling the
privately owned loans all at once are more easily seen when it is
assumed that debt service payments are cancelled as they come
due. Nonetheless, this is a more complex case to illustrate than
the case of the government cancelling these loans. Therefore,
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
+Loans(p) +RBs(p) +RBs(p) +D
PI
(p) +D
PI
(p)
-Loans(p)
-Loans(p) -Eq
Fed
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+RBs(p) +RBs(p) +D
PI
(p) -Loans(p) +D
PI
(p)
-Eq
Fed
(p) +Eq
HH
(p) -Loans(p)
Table 2.23 Federal Reserve Purchases and Cancels Privately Owned Student Loans
Fed Purchases
Private Loans
Fed Cancels
Private Loans
Totals
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans(p) -Eq
Fed
(p) -Loans(p)
+Eq
HH
(p)
+RBs(i) +RBs(i) +Eq
Banks
(i)
-Eq
Fed
(i)
-Tsy Acct(p,i) -Eq
Govt
(p,i) -Tsy Acct(p,i)
+Eq
Fed
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys (p,i) -RBs(p,i) -RBs(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i) -D
PI
(p,i)
+Tsy Acct(p,i) +Tsys(p,i)
+Tsys(p,i) -Loans(p) -RBs(p) -RBs(p) -D
PI
(p,i) -Loans(p) -D
PI
(p,i)
-Eq
Govt
(p,i) +Eq
Banks
(i) +Eq
HH
(p) +Tsys(p,i)
Table 2.24 Federal Reserve Purchases and Cancels Privately Owned Student Loans as Payments Come Due—Actual
Transactions
Fed Cancels
Principal Now
Due
Fed Pays
IOR
Fed Reduces
Remittances
Government
Issues
Securities
Totals
34 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
only the T-accounts for the actual transactions are shown—the
counterfactual or “relative to no cancellation scenario is omit-
ted. Table 2.24 shows the actual transactions for this scenario.
The first transaction is the Fed cancelling principal now due.
The second transaction is the Fed paying interest on reserves
on the reserve balances created when it purchased the privately
owned loans in Table 2.23. Together, the cancelled principal
and IOR payment (which raises banks’ equity) reduce the Fed’s
remittances by the combined amount in the third transaction.
This reduces the government’s budget position by the same
amount and leads the government to issue new securities in
kind. From the totals, the government has issued new securities
in the amount of principal plus interest. This amount is equal
to the Fed’s IOR payment from its purchase of the loans and the
reduction in the Fed’s reserve balances; in other words, the Fed’s
liabilities created by the purchase of the loans—the reserve bal-
ances—are reduced by the amount of the principal due, while
the government’s liabilities increase to offset.
Over the life of the loans, the Fed’s reserve balances created
by the purchase will fall each year, eventually to zero, while the
Treasury’s liabilities will rise eventually to the amount of the
Fed’s original purchase plus all IOR payments made through-
out. Thus, unlike Table 2.12, in which the government issued
securities up front to purchase the loans and thereafter new
government liabilities were only equal to the annual debt
service on these securities, here the governments liabilities
increase each period by the amount of principal and interest
due. Nevertheless, there is once again ultimately no “free lunch
from having the Fed carry out the cancellation, as the end result
is that the full amount of the original purchase plus interest is
eventually added to the government’s liabilities.
Potential options to avoid costs to the federal government of
student loan cancellation carried out by the Federal Reserve
The keys to understanding the argument to this point—that
there is no “free lunch from having the Fed carry out the can-
cellation rather than the federal government—are as follows:
(1) the Fed’s surplus capital above $10 billion each year is remit-
ted to the Treasury, and (2) the Fed necessarily provides interest
on reserve balances (or some alternative to it, like reverse repur-
chase agreements) at its target rate in the event that the quantity
of reserve balances supplied is beyond the quantity demanded
at the target rate. Nevertheless, this section explores two options
(both highly theoretical) that could potentially enable the Fed
to carry out a student loan cancellation while also obtaining
a “free lunch”—that is, where the costs would not ultimately
affect the federal government’s budget.
12
As suggested previ-
ously, it is highly unlikely that the Fed would desire to carry out
student loan cancellation. Moreover, it is questionable whether
the Fed has the legal authority to do so—and even if it techni-
cally does have such authority, exercising it may result in legal
and political repercussions for the Fed’s prized independence.
Consequently, it is presumed that an act of Congress and presi-
dential signature would be required to allow (or force, as the
case may be) the Fed to engage in any such actions (Carrillo et
al. forthcoming).
The first option recognizes that the Fed funds itself mostly
via interest on its portfolio of securities and loans. As several
rounds of quantitative easing since the financial crisis have
shown, the Fed’s profits can rise substantially as its balance sheet
expands. In theory at least, as the Fed cancels the student loans
that it owns, it could begin purchasing other financial assets,
and the earnings on the latter could offset the losses, thereby
not affecting remittances to the Treasury. Again, this is all quite
theoretical. The Fed’s losses from student loan cancellation
could rival or even significantly exceed the profits it currently
earns on a balance sheet of around $3 trillion in a given year.
Any proposal that the Fed purchase perhaps another $3 trillion
in financial assets—or a lot more than this—would quickly run
into many difficulties, such as (most obviously) the potential
effect on interest rates and asset prices.
A second option would be to expand on the Fed’s existing
accounting practices regarding operating losses. Currently, if
the Fed experiences an operating loss in any week, it capitalizes
the losses as a deferred asset” that is a negative liability rather
than reducing surplus capital; remittances to the Treasury are
not paid until an operating profit is run large enough to offset
any previous operating losses. If the Fed were instead able to
isolate losses from cancelling student loans from the rest of its
operating profits—perhaps by deferring them permanently—it
could in theory result in the losses not negatively affecting remit-
tances to the Treasury (Carrillo et al. forthcoming). In this case,
the Fed would create a separate, deferred account on its asset
side, rather than its liability side. In terms of balance sheets, the
T-account transactions would look like those in Table 2.25. An
alternative could be for the Fed to not write down the loans and
its equity but instead capitalize the losses or write down both
as an asset and as a deferred asset” on the liability side (similar
to loan-loss provisioning by banks), which Table 2.26 presents
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 35
(“deferred loan loss” is used here rather than deferred asset” to
avoid potential confusion from crediting an asset as a liability).
In either case (from Table 2.25 or 2.26), under the appro-
priate legal circumstances the Fed’s operating profits—and thus
its surplus capital and subsequent remittances to the Treasury—
could be shielded from being affected by the losses it would oth-
erwise incur from carrying out student loan cancellation.
In conclusion, while both options discussed here are not
“usual” approaches to managing the Fed’s operating profits,
they are potential avenues for obtaining a “free lunch in car-
rying out student loan cancellation. Obviously either option
would be quite controversial, and would likely be opposed by
the Fed as stridently as anyone else. In the absence of either of
these two options being instituted, there is no “free lunch in
having the Fed carry out the debt cancellation, and it is erro-
neous to consider such actions by the Fed as analogous to its
earlier quantitative easing operations.
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
-Loans No Change
-Loans
Eq
Fed
+Capitalized +Eq
HH
Loan
Writedow n
Table 2.25 Federal Reserve Capitalizes Losses from Cancelling Student Loan Debt Service
Fed Cancels
Loan
Payments
Federal Government Federal Reserve Banks Student Loan Borrowers Private Investors
A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E A L/E
No Change No Change
-Loans
Loan Values Eq
Fed
+Capitalized +Deferred +Eq
HH
Loan
Loan
Losses Losses
Table 2.26 Federal Reserve Capitalizes Losses from Cancelling Student Loan Debt Service without Writing Down Loans
Fed Cancels
Loan
Payments
36 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Section 3: Simulating Student Debt
Cancellation
We simulated the student debt cancellation using two macro-
econometric models in order to examine the implications of
student debt cancellation and incorporate feedback effects that
go beyond financial statement analysis. This section presents the
results from simulations of a debt cancellation carried out within
the Moody’s model and the US version of the Fair model.
13
Feedback effects necessarily omitted from financial statement
analysis of the mechanics of student debt cancellation are explic-
itly accounted for in these simulations. At the same time, it is very
important to understand that many potential effects are out-
side the scope of macroeconometric models. For instance, nei-
ther model explicitly integrates different income or wealth tiers
within the private sector, business startup decisions, and so forth.
To the degree that benefits beyond the scope of these simulations
are present (discussed later in this section), the results presented
here represent a subset of the benefits (or costs, as the case might
be) of student debt cancellation. Both models are well regarded
among economists. The Moody’s model is well-known among
professional macroeconomic forecasters and is frequently refer-
enced in the press, particularly in the context of policy debates.
For its part, simulations of and econometric investigations into
the Fair model have been the subject of several dozen academic
publications over the past 40 years or more.
Models and Assumptions Used for Simulating
Student Debt Cancellation
Introduction to the Moody’s model
The Moody’s model is the macroeconomic forecasting model
used by Moody’s and Economy.com. It has around 1,800 vari-
ables and can best be described as ‘Keynesian in the short run,
and classical in the long run’” (Zandi and Hoyt 2015). The
model is “structural, taking a middle ground between pure
time-series-based models and those founded on strict micro-
economic theoretical foundations, which means it attempts to
balance theoretical assumptions with econometric evidence
(Zandi and Hoyt 2015). The methodological documentation of
Moody’s model by Zandi and Hoyt explains that,
By taking a middle ground between theory and data,
this approach attains neither the theoretical elegance of
the DSGE [Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium]
approach or the empirical flexibility of a VAR [Vector
Autoregression]. At the same time, however, it manages
to avoid the shortcomings of either one; imposing theory
to restrict the flexibility of econometric specifications
allows more efficient estimation and greater explanatory
power than a VAR can achieve. However, structural mac-
roeconomic models do not require some of the extreme
and somewhat unrealistic assumptions that render
DSGEs susceptible to misspecification. (2015, 2)
A structural model is built via numerous aggregative equa-
tions that have a grounding in macroeconomic theory; these
“stochastic” equations are then estimated econometrically
either individually or simultaneously. The econometric regres-
sions determine key variables that are then inserted into identity
equations (such as those from National Income and Product
Accounts or Flow of Funds) in order to determine the rest of the
model’s endogenous variables through an iterative method that
solves all of the identities simultaneously. As Zandi and Hoyt
(2015, 2) put it, the strength of structural models “is the great
detail they can provide.
Though VARs and DSGEs can incorporate no more
than a few variables of interest such as aggregate GDP,
a benchmark bond yield, and CPI inflation, structural
macroeconomic models are able to specify and gener-
ate forecasts for a rich array of macroeconomic data,
detailing the composition of both spending and indus-
trial activity, the entire maturity yield curve and many
other interest rates, and prices for goods, services, and
assets throughout the economy.
The paper by Zandi and Hoyt provides the specification
and estimation results for several of the model’s stochastic
equations, including consumer services spending, vehicle sales,
investment in industrial equipment, private inventories, goods
exports, vehicle and parts imports, hourly compensation, the
federal funds rate, rates on the 10-year Treasury note, corporate
profits, aggregate hours worked, industry employment, labor
force, wages and salaries, single-family permits, and a housing
price index. Several of these are discussed below within the con-
text of the simulations of student debt cancellation.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 37
Introduction to the Fair model
The Fair model is a large-scale, structural, macroeconometric
model designed by Ray Fair at Yale University. Created in the
1970s, the model’s structure has changed little across more than
40 years of business cycles and macroeconomic events. The “US
model” version of the Fair model has about 225 variables within
25 stochastic equations and 100 identity equations that com-
pletely integrate National Income and Product Accounts and
Flow of Funds data. The simulations presented in this report
are via the US model because it is updated quarterly; Fair’s
“Multicountry” version of the model, which includes the US
model’s 125 equations but then adds roughly 1,550 additional
equations for around 50 other countries, has not been updated
since 2013. Several books, published papers, and a website are
the primary sources for the Fair model.
14
The approach to build-
ing the model’s structural equations is derived from the Cowles
Commission, which, like the design of the Moody’s model,
uses macroeconomic theory to guide the design of stochastic
equations that are then estimated (in the Fair model’s case, via
two-stage least squares techniques) and repeatedly tested for
statistical significance, misspecification, the structure of error
terms, stability, predictive ability, and so forth.
15
The entire
models are then rigorously tested for consistency with empiri-
cal evidence and predictive ability (Fair 2013, 2004, 1992). Fair
presents updated estimates for structural equation coefficients
and single equation tests each quarter in an Appendix” posted
to his website. His published research argues that the Fair model
dominates VAR, New Keynesian, and Real Business Cycle models
in predicting real GDP both four and eight quarters ahead (Fair
2007, 2004). Overall, like Zandi and Hoyt, Fair finds the DSGE
models to be less useful than the larger structural econometric
models for real-world policy analysis.
Whereas the Moody’s model has a self-described “Classical
core”—or long-run assumptions based upon estimated supply-
side fundamentals—to complement a more “Keynesian short
run, the Fair model is more traditionally Keynesian through-
out. In contrast to the Moody’s model, Fair’s econometric stud-
ies have rejected the so-called nonaccelerating inflation rate of
unemployment (NAIRU) dynamics. To be more precise, Fair
finds that the more accurate relationship between inflation
and unemployment is nonlinear, whereby inflation is not very
responsive to unemployment rates across a wide range, but
could become much steeper at very low unemployment rates,
perhaps around 2 percent (that is, at very low unemployment
rates, inflation could rise substantially). To be clear, though, with
so few real-world observations, Fair’s econometric studies were
not able to entirely confirm or reject the likelihood of a steep rise
in inflation at very low unemployment rates (Fair 2013, 147–60).
Both models have been used to project events in the mac-
roeconomy. The economic proposals for both 2016 presidential
candidates were simulated in the Moody’s model. The model is
updated monthly for incoming macroeconomic data in order
to provide new macroeconomic forecasts and other simula-
tions presented in various Moody’s publications (Zandi et al.
2016; Zandi, Lafakis, and Ozimek 2016). Fair’s books from 2004
and 2013 provide summaries of numerous earlier published
papers (often in leading macroeconomic journals) forecasting
the effects of the Obama stimulus (the 2009 American Recovery
and Reinvestment Act); effects of monetary and fiscal policies;
econometric analyses of unemployment, inflation, and produc-
tion; financial crises; and so forth. Finally, Fair predicted the
1990s stock market bubble after structural stability tests of the
Fair model’s stochastic equations showed that only the variable
associated with capital gains in equities had evidence of a struc-
tural break.
16
Assumptions for the simulated student debt cancellation
The version of student debt cancellation simulated in the mod-
els is based upon the mechanics provided in the previous sec-
tions: the federal government cancels student loans owned by
the Department of Education (ED) and takes over payments
owed on privately owned student loans. Assumptions for the
simulations are the following:
1) The student debt cancellation occurs at the beginning of
2017. For the first quarter of 2017, we assume debt in each
of the three categories of student loans to be at the follow-
ing levels:
Debt owned by the ED = $1,024 billion.
Debt owned by private investors and government-
guaranteed = $277 billion.
Debt owned by private investors and not
government-guaranteed = $105 billion.
2) From the perspective of those borrowers servicing student
loans prior to the debt cancellation, the effect of cancelling
the ED-owned loans and taking over payments of loans
owned by private investors is to essentially cancel all of their
student loan debt at the beginning of 2017. In other words,
they will act as if their student loans are cancelled. The sum
of the three categories of student loans is $1.406 trillion;
38 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
borrowers currently servicing student loans will feel as if
their net wealth has increased by this amount. Further, the
income that households would have devoted to servicing
their loans is now available for households to spend, save,
or borrow against. These two effects—the rise in net finan-
cial wealth from the debt cancellation and additional dis-
posable income previously devoted to debt service—are the
avenues through which the debt cancellation stimulates the
macroeconomy in the simulations.
17
3) From the perspective of the private investors owning stu-
dent loans, there is no change, as they continue to receive
the payments they would receive in the absence of the can-
cellation. The difference is that the borrowers are now in
possession of greater discretionary income, since they are
no longer the ones making these payments.
4) For simplicity of comparison, in the absence of the cancel-
lation, all student loans owned by the ED and all privately
issued, not government-guaranteed loans are assumed to
have otherwise been paid down in equal principal install-
ments over 10 years, in accordance with the ED’s standard
repayment plan. All privately issued loans that are guar-
anteed by the government are assumed to have otherwise
been paid off by the end of 2020, also in equal principal
installments. This scenario also assumes a 10-year repay-
ment plan for privately issued, government-guaranteed
student loans, since the federally guaranteed student loan
program ended in 2010.
5) Interest rates on the three types of student loans are
assumed to be the following:
Debt owned by the ED = 4.6 percent (consistent
with current law).
Debt owned by private investors and government-
guaranteed = the previous quarter’s short-term
interest rate (determined within the models’
simulations) plus 2.3 percent (consistent with
current law).
Debt owned by private investors and not government-
guaranteed = 10 percent (as a proxy average for
interest rates on current outstanding loans).
18
Baseline values and macroeconometric simulation
Simulations require a baseline level for comparison and evalua-
tion of the simulated changes. That is, the simulation of a policy
change itself is only meaningful relative to a model’s baseline,
since the latter represents the model’s simulated values without
the policy in place. This is particularly the case for simulations
involving model forecasts for more than a few years, as struc-
tural models thereafter converge to a “trend” or longer-run
path that may have little to offer in terms of a useful forecast
without careful adjustments to many exogenous variables. For
the Fair model, the baseline is the forecast for the model from
2017 to 2026. Fair currently provides forecasts on his website
through 2022 only. To simulate 2023 to 2026, we extrapolated
Fair’s assumptions for changes in certain exogenous variables—
all of which are reported on his website—forward to 2026.
Additionally, Fair’s empirical research finds macroeconomically
significant age-related effects, such as the ratio of working-age
to non-working-age people. To incorporate these, US Census
population projections were used to design the variables Fair
incorporates into stochastic equations. The Fair model simula-
tions were carried out using the Fair-Parke program, available
on Fair’s website. For Moody’s model, the baseline is defined as
the model’s projection for 2017–26.
19
We demonstrate the relevance of one additional policy
assumption in the simulations by presenting results under two
scenarios for each model. First, we simulate the models with the
Fed’s interest rate reaction function included—that is, the Fed’s
interest rate target adjusts to “lean against” macroeconomic
changes associated with the cancellation. Next, we simulate an
alternative scenario in which the Fed’s interest rate reaction
function is “turned off. In other words, the behavior of the
short-term interest rate in these latter simulations will be iden-
tical to that in the respective baseline simulations. The rationale
for turning off the Fed is that the student debt cancellation pro-
duces little to no inflationary impact in either model (shown
and discussed below). Despite the Federal Reserve’s essentially
mechanical responses to lower unemployment assumed within
the models as the positive macroeconomic effects of the debt
cancellation appear, there might be little actual rationale for
real-world central bankers to raise interest rates and subse-
quently dampen these positive effects.
It is important to recall that in both models there is no
breakdown of the private sector into borrowers and nonbor-
rowers of student loans. In the Moody’s model, there is some
capacity to break down the consumption function into groups
related to income or wealth in order to account for differing
propensities to consume, but our simulation does not account
for which income or wealth cohort is benefiting from the debt
cancellation. Instead, both models have a “household sec-
tor” that supplies labor, purchases consumption goods (also
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 39
broken down into multiple categories in both models), and
buys houses. In the Fair model, there are relative-sized age
cohorts, and also gender effects for consumption and labor sup-
ply, but the model does not enable directly tying age and gender
cohorts to the distribution of debt relief from the cancellation
within the simulations. This all means that the simulated mac-
roeconomic impacts for both models are “general” or “average”
in the sense that they assume that the increase in net wealth and
reduced debt service benefits the entire household sector, not
specific components of the household sector. Depending upon
how the benefits would actually be distributed—for instance, to
younger individuals that might then be more likely to purchase
a home—the macroeconomic impacts could be more signifi-
cant than reported here.
Finally, as is explained below in the discussion of the
impacts of the student debt cancellation on the government’s
budget position (and elaborated on in Appendix B), the presen-
tation in Section 2 regarding the financial statement effects for
the federal government of cancelling the ED’s loans needs to be
reconciled with the approach taken in the simulations. The base-
line case for both models—inherent in the “assumptions for the
simulated student cancellation presented above—is a scenario
in which no cancellation of student loans occurs and all the
loans are paid back over the 10-year period. Consequently, the
net budgetary impacts for the federal government in the simu-
lations are presented as a change in comparison to this base-
line, not in comparison to the government’s current budgetary
position. As explained in Section 2, the costs of funding the
ED’s loans have already been incurred; cancelling these loans
merely requires continued servicing of the securities issued at
that time. Although the foregone interest and principal pay-
ments on the ED’s loans both affect the government’s budget
position in comparison to the counterfactual assumed in the
simulations (a baseline of no cancellation and continued repay-
ment), the impact on the actual government budget position
and outstanding liabilities (that is, the national debt) would be
far smaller compared to its current levels.
Simulation Results
Turning to the results of the simulations, the discussion here
first covers the main macroeconomic variables (real GDP,
employment, and inflation). Thereafter, other results of inter-
est from the simulation are presented. All, or nearly all, of the
related figures show simulated effects relative to the baseline
levels noted above for the respective models, since those are the
actual impacts of the debt cancellation within the simulations.
Figure 3.1 shows the total contribution of the cancellation
to real GDP (in 2016 $ billions) over 10 years in all four simula-
tions—the Fair model, the Fair model with the Fed’s reaction
function turned off (reported in this and subsequent figures as
“no Fed” for both models), the Moody’s model, and the Moody’s
model with no Fed reaction function. For the Fair model, the
cancellation creates $943 billion in total inflation-adjusted GDP
(or $94 billion per year, on average) “with the Fed, which rises
to about $1,083 billion total (or $108 billion per year, on aver-
age) when the Fed is turned off. For the Moody’s model, with
the Fed the cancellation results in an additional $252 billion
total inflation-adjusted GDP (just under $25 billion per year, on
average), which rises to $861 billion total when the Fed is turned
off (just under $86 billion per year, on average).
20, 21
As can be seen in Figure 3.1, three of the simulation results
are very similar, while the Moody’s model with the Fed presents
a significantly smaller total effect on real GDP. Figure 3.2 shows
the models’ results for each year of the simulation. Particularly
interesting is that all four simulations are similar in magnitude
and pattern through 2020, though the Fair model results with-
out the Fed are about $45 billion above the other three simu-
lations, on average. In all four simulations, the cancellation
creates a significant increase in real GDP during 2017–20 that
peaks in 2018. After 2021, the increases are smaller because (1)
the initial wealth effect of the cancellation is decaying over time,
and (2) the government-guaranteed student loans owned by the
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
1,200
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s Moody’s No Fed
Figure 3.1 Total Additional Real GDP Resulting from
Student Loan Cancellation for 2017–26
Source: Authorscalculations
$ Billions (2016)
40 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
private sector are assumed to be paid off in 2020 in the absence
of the cancellation (that is, the stimulus of additional income
to borrowers ends in 2020, since without the cancellation the
loans would have been paid off by then). For both models, the
effect of turning off the Fed’s reaction function is that the GDP
increase is higher and tails off a bit more slowly, as the Fed’s
interest rate target does not rise above the baseline forecasts of
the models.
Starting in 2021, the Moody’s simulations with the Fed
show a substantially smaller rise in GDP relative to the other
three simulations, and even show a subtraction from real GDP
during 2022–26. While the other three simulations stabilize in
the range of an additional $40–60 billion in real GDP during
2022–26, clearly the Moody’s model is very sensitive to changes
in the Fed’s interest rate policy. This is unlike the Fair model
for these years, in which the simulation results with and with-
out the Fed turn out quite similar to one another in pattern and
magnitude. An important consideration for understanding and
evaluating the simulation results and their implications for the
cancellation, therefore, is whether or not such assumed changes
in the Fed’s target rate are warranted as a response to the mac-
roeconomic effects of the cancellation policy. This relates spe-
cifically to the cancellations effect on inflation in the figures and
analysis below, since the Fed’s stated long-run goal is low infla-
tion rates that enable maximum sustainable growth in real GDP.
Figure 3.3 shows the average unemployment rates in the
two models for the entire 10-year period. Recall from above that
the baseline values for the models are not on their own signifi-
cant—of actual interest are the differences between baseline val-
ues and simulation values. The simulations for the entire period
show unemployment rates 0.22 percentage points and 0.25 per-
centage points below the baseline values for the Fair model sim-
ulations with and without the Fed, respectively. For the Moody’s
simulations, the cancellation reduces the unemployment rate by
0.13 percentage points with the Fed and 0.36 percentage points
without the Fed.
Figure 3.4 shows the reduction in unemployment rates
from baseline values for each year of all four debt cancellation
simulations. As with real GDP in Figure 3.2, the reduction in
unemployment rates is greatest during 2017–20, with an aver-
age reduction of about 0.4 percentage points for the Fair model
simulations (peaking at 0.48 percentage points and 0.55 per-
centage points for the with-Fed and without-Fed simulations,
respectively) and 0.6 percentage points for the Moody’s simula-
tions (peaking at 0.87 and 0.88 percentage points, respectively).
During 2022–26, the Moody’s simulation with the Fed’s target
rate rule in place is once again an outlier, with unemployment
Fair Model
Fair Model No Fed
Moody’s
Moody’s No Fed
-100
-50
0
50
100
150
200
250
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Sour
ce: Authorscalculations
Figure 3.2 Additional Real GDP Resulting from Student
Loan Canc
ellation for Each Year of the Simulation
$ Billions (2016)
4.00
4.25
4.50
4.75
5.00
5.25
5.50
Figure 3.3 Average Unemployment Rate for Each Student
Debt Cancellation Simulation
Sour
ce: Authorscalculations
Fair Model Baseline
Fair Model Baseline + Cancellation
Fair Model Baseline + Cancellation with No Fed
Moody’s Baseline
Moody’s Baseline + Cancellation
Moody’s Baseline + Cancellation with No Fed
Percent
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 41
rates actually modestly higher (0.19 percentage points higher,
on average) than the baseline levels. The other three simula-
tions, on the other hand, average fairly stable reductions during
2022–26 of 0.13 percentage points (Fair model with the Fed),
0.19 percentage points (Fair model without the Fed), and 0.21
percentage points (Moody’s without the Fed).
Figure 3.5 presents the number of additional jobs created as
a result of the cancellation in each year. The job creation results
in the Fair model peak in 2018–20 at 1.18 million additional
jobs per year with the Fed’s interest rate rule in place and 1.44
million with the Fed’s rule turned off. For the Moody’s model,
the job creation effects peak at about 1.53 million jobs with the
Fed’s reaction function, and 1.55 million without it. In all four
simulations, job creation relative to the baseline tails off thereaf-
ter, but again the Moody’s simulation with the Fed is an outlier.
While the other three simulations show job creation stabiliz-
ing at 400,000 jobs above the respective baseline levels during
2022–26, the Moody’s simulation with the Fed shows a worsen-
ing economy and thus job reductions during this period.
By way of comparison, job creation in the United States
from 2010 to 2015 averaged 2.23 million per year. The simu-
lations thus suggest that two years after inception, student
debt cancellation alone might create 50 percent to 70 percent
as many jobs in its peak year as the current economic expan-
sion creates in an average year, and could continue to sustain
about one-third of the job creation seen in the cancellations
peak years throughout the duration of the cancellation. As with
the unemployment rates, the simulations also suggest that the
Moody’s model job creation projections are more sensitive to
the state of the economy than are the Fair model’s, as a greater
increase in real GDP in the latter leads to about the same peak
job creation as in the former. And yet again, there is significantly
greater sensitivity to the Fed’s interest rate reaction function in
the Moody’s model. Although the results for the Moody’s simu-
lation without the Fed are similar to those for both Fair model
simulations, after the first four years the Moody’s simulation
with the Fed’s reaction function produces very different results
from the other three simulations.
Figure 3.6 presents results for inflation. In the Moody’s
model, the inflation measure is the Consumer Price Index (here-
after, CPI); for the Fair model, the measure is the model’s own
index for firm-sector pricing, which has historically been highly
correlated with standard measures of consumer price infla-
tion like the CPI and the Personal Consumption Expenditures
Figure 3.5 Additional Private-Sector Jobs Resulting from
Student Loan Cancellation
0
250,000
500,000
750,000
1,000,000
1,250,000
1,500,000
1,750,000
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
-500,000
-250,000
Fair Model
Fair Model No Fed
Moody’s
Moody’s No Fed
Source: Authorscalculations
-1.0
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Figure 3.4 Reduction in Unemployment Rate for Each Year
of the Simulation
Percent
Fair Model
Fair Model No Fed
Moody’s
Moody’s No Fed
Source: Authorscalculations
42 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Price Index (PCEPI). In the Fair model, the inflationary effect
of student debt cancellation is modest, peaking at just below
0.3 percentage points of additional inflation (that is, compared
to the baseline) with the Fed’s interest rate rule in place, and a
bit above this level with the Fed’s rule turned off. After 2020,
consistent with the tailing off of real GDP contributions noted
above, the inflationary impact is actually negative—that is, the
cancellation reduces inflation in these years. For the Moody’s
model, the inflationary effects are even smaller—essentially at
zero, given that they never rise above 0.09 percentage points.
Overall, because even the largest effect on inflation in a sin-
gle year in either model (0.32 percentage points in 2018 in the
Fair model simulation with no reaction from the Fed’s interest
rate rule) is of little macroeconomic significance, it is at least
arguable that the Fed would not respond to the student debt
cancellation by raising its interest rate target. Recall that this is
the rationale for including simulations for both models in which
the Fed’s interest rate rule is turned off.
22
Stated differently, a
case can be made that the Fed would not, or at least should not,
react to the cancellation by raising interest rates given its stated
goal of keeping inflation from rising above its target. If so, the
Moody’s simulation with the Fed’s target rate reaction function
included—the clear outlier in these simulations—is not as use-
ful a guide to the cancellations impacts as the other three sim-
ulations. Even the Fair model simulation with the Fed’s target
rate rule turned on might be of less interest, although (1) the
simulations with and without the Fed’s rule are not very dis-
similar (that is, the Fair model is less sensitive to interest rate
target changes than the Moody’s model), and (2) the inflation-
ary impacts of the cancellation, though small in terms of mac-
roeconomic significance, were significantly greater in the early
years of the Fair model simulation than in the Moody’s model.
Figures 3.7 and 3.8 show the simulated effects of debt can-
cellation on nominal interest rates. Figure 3.7 presents the Fed’s
response to the cancellation in both models when its reaction
function is turned on. In the Fair model, the Fed responds by
increasing its target rate by around 0.5 percentage points above
the baseline in 2018 and 2019; thereafter, the increases slowly
taper off until the Fed’s target rate settles at around 0.2 percent-
age points above the 2023–26 baseline.
In the Moody’s model, the Fed’s reaction is very simi-
lar during the first six years of the simulation—the Fed raises
its interest rate target by 0.4 to 0.46 percentage points during
2019–20, after which the effect of the cancellation tails off to
almost nothing by the end of 2026. In fact, by 2024 the Fed is
setting the interest rate slightly lower than the baseline level.
In other words, the Fed’s early interest rate hikes that peak at
0.46 percentage points in 2020 have a sizeable enough impact in
slowing the economy that by the end of the simulation the Fed
is reversing course to attempt mild stimulus. This is consistent
Figure 3.6 Inflation Impacts of Student Debt Cancellation
-0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Percent
Fair Model
Fair Model No Fed
Moody’s
Moody’s No Fed
Source: Authorscalculations
Figure 3.7 Effect of Student Debt Cancellation on the
Federal Reserve’s Interest Rate Target—Differences from
Baseline Va lues
Sour
ce: Authorscalculations
-0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Percent
Fair Model
Moody’s
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 43
with the results for the Moody’s model presented in the previous
figures. Most importantly, this again suggests that the Moody’s
results with the Fed’s target rule turned on are an outlier here.
From Figure 3.6, there is little evidence that the Fed should raise
interest rates, while from Figure 3.7, the Fed is only modestly
raising interest rates. The Moody’s model is clearly very sensi-
tive to changes in the Fed’s interest rate target, as a very modest
0.46 percentage point interest rate hike is sufficient to bring the
stimulus effect of the student debt cancellation (an immediate
$1.4 trillion increase in net financial wealth and a reduction in
debt service on this amount over 10 years) to an effective stand-
still (or worse) by the end of 2021.
The effects on the 10-year Treasury rate in Figure 3.8 are
also not large. The peaks in both models are not much differ-
ent—0.34 percentage points in the Fair model and 0.54 per-
centage points in the Moody’s model, both including the Fed’s
interest rate reaction function. The Moody’s model peaks in
2022, two years after the Fair model’s peak in 2020, following
the pattern of the impacts on the federal funds rate in Figure
3.7. The difference between the student debt cancellations aver-
age effects on the 10-year Treasury rate in the two models is
even smaller—the rate averages being 0.25 percentage points
higher than the baseline in the Fair model and 0.38 percentage
points higher in the Moody’s model.
Figure 3.8 only presents results without the Fed’s reac-
tion function in the case of the Moody’s model. Unlike in the
Moody’s model, the long-term interest rate in the Fair model
showed a negligible change from its baseline value when the
Fed’s reaction was turned off. The reason for this difference
is that while the Moody’s model incorporates the government
debt-to-GDP ratio as an explanatory variable for the 10-year
Treasury note, the Fair model does not. This is one of the sig-
nificant differences in the two models. The Fair model takes a
more traditional Keynesian approach to explaining the 10-year
rate’s spread above the short-term rate: through lagged values
of the spread and changes in both the short-term rate and in
lagged values of the spread. The Moody’s model incorporation
of the national debt-to-GDP ratio, on the other hand, is con-
sistent with its self-described “Classical” long-run structure.
23, 24
In the Moody’s model simulations, the effects on the 10-year
Treasury rate when the Fed’s reaction function is turned off
average a 0.27 percentage point increase above the baseline. In
other words, the impact of changes in the government’s budget
position induced by the cancellation amount to a 0.11 percent-
age point increase in the 10-year Treasury rate (a 0.38 percent-
age point increase on average with the Fed’s reaction function,
minus 0.27 percentage points on average without the Fed’s reac-
tion function). If one considers the normal variation in longer-
term Treasury rates, this 0.11 percentage point difference is
Source: Authorscalculations
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Figure 3.8 Effect of Student Debt Cancellation on the
10-Year Treasury Rate—Differences from Baseline Values
Fair Model
Moody’s
Moody’s No Fed
Percent
Figure 3.9 Average Annual Deficit Impacts of Student Debt
Cancellation (percent of GDP)
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1.0
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s Moody’s No Fed
Percent
Sour
ce: Authorscalculations
Deficit Impact
Deficit Impact Less Interest
44 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
within the realm of “statistical noise”; indeed, the increases in
the longer-term rates shown here resulting from the debt can-
cellation are not of macroeconomic significance relative to his-
torical changes.
25
A large-scale debt cancellation can be expected to worsen
the federal government’s budget position absent extraordinarily
strong feedback effects from the programs macroeconomic
stimulus. Figure 3.9 presents two separate views for each of the
simulations. First, the annual deficit impacts—that is, after the
cancellation affects macroeconomic performance, which feeds
back to the governments budget position—are between 0.65
percent and 0.75 percent of GDP in the Fair model simulations
and 0.75 percent of GDP in the Moody’s simulation without
the Fed’s rule in effect. This is consistent with the smaller mac-
roeconomic impact in the latter scenario, which would thereby
have a smaller positive feedback effect on the budget. In the
Moody’s simulation with the Fed’s rule in effect, however, the
net budget deficit increase (0.89 percent of GDP on average)
is larger than the direct costs of the cancellation. This is due
to the poorer macroeconomic performance of the economy in
that scenario, which negatively affects the government’s budget.
Second, the simulations here assumed both that the govern-
ment was already running a deficit (that is, the baseline for both
models is that the federal government is in a deficit position at
least through 2026) and that there were no budgetary offsets
to the cancellation via spending cuts or revenue increases. As
a result, the deficit effects include increased government debt
service. However, in the event that the government begins in
a surplus position or offsets the costs of the cancellation, this
debt service would not exist or be less than estimated here. This
would also be true if interest rates turn out to be significantly
lower than is assumed in the models’ baseline cases (these base-
lines assume interest rates in the later years of the simulations
rise higher than what the Fed’s policymakers have been fore-
casting). The columns in Figure 3.9 labeled “Deficit Impact Less
Interest” show that the average noninterest deficit effects of the
cancellation are about 0.6 percent of GDP in both Fair model
simulations and also in the Moody’s simulation without the
Fed’s rule in effect. With the Fed’s rule in effect, the noninterest
deficit effect is 0.69 percent of GDP for the Moody’s model.
From the earlier discussion in this section of the two mod-
els’ baseline forecasts, the deficit impacts presented in Figure
3.9 significantly overstate how the government’s actual budget
position and outstanding liabilities would be affected, relative
to their current levels. Appendix B explains this in detail as it
progresses through to an estimate of the more relevant average
annual deficit impacts of the student debt cancellation: between
0.29 and 0.37 percent of GDP for the two Fair model simula-
tions and the Moody’s simulation without the Fed’s rule in
effect. These figures are not adjusted for debt service, and thus
are adjustments to the larger amounts in Figure 3.9. Adjusting
again for debt service would reduce these estimates still further.
Figure 3.10 presents the average multiplier effects of student
debt cancellation. The multiplier effect here is the total increase
in nominal GDP during the full simulation period divided by
the sum of the government’s total revenue loss from foregone
debt service and the spending increases on debt service paid
to private investors during the full simulation period (in other
words, the total direct costs of the cancellation). For the Fair
model, the multiplier of 1.32 (with the Fed’s reaction function
in place) and 1.5 (without the Fed’s reaction function) are at the
higher end of—though still in line with—those found in other
empirical studies, though less so when one considers that part
of the stimulus is from the wealth effect of private debt cancel-
lation (Eichengreen and O’Rourke 2012; Blanchard and Leigh
2013; Zandi 2008). The multipliers in the Moody’s model are
smaller. With the Fed’s reaction function in place, the multiplier
is 0.56, which is at the low end for most studies, particularly if
one considers again the wealth effect at work in the simulation.
Without the Fed’s interest rate reaction function, the multiplier
for the Moody’s model is 1.04, which is in a typical range. Again,
if the economy is less sensitive to the Fed’s interest rate increases
Sour
ce: Authorscalculations
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s Moody’s No Fed
Figure 3.10 Average Multiplier Effects of Student Debt
Cancellation
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 45
than the Moody’s model suggests, the weight of the evidence
falls in the 1.04 to 1.50 range for the multiplier.
Ignoring for the moment the wealth effect of the debt can-
cellation, it is worth noting that the multiplier’s path in these
simulations is through one of the traditionally smaller mul-
tipliers, at least from a Keynesian perspective. The cancella-
tion effectively raises borrowers’ incomes, and therefore has a
smaller multiplier effect than government stimulus via direct
purchases in these models. In other words, those that believe
direct increases in household income—as in a tax cut—will
have larger multipliers than traditional Keynesian models sug-
gest should also believe that multiplier effects of the debt can-
cellation will be at least as large as those reported here (if not
larger).
Recalling that the analysis in Appendix B of the costs of
student debt cancellation is more relevant for understanding
the costs relative to the current level of the national debt, one
can consider the multiplier effects of the cancellation from that
perspective. In this case, the multiplier effects rise to 2.79 and
3.33 for the Fair model simulations with and without the Fed’s
rule in effect, respectively. For the Moody’s model, the multipli-
ers are 1.03 with the Fed’s rule in place and 1.94 with the Fed’s
rule turned off.
Finally, in the Fair model the debt cancellation leads budget
positions to improve at the state level as a result of the stronger
macroeconomy, as shown in Figure 3.11 (in nominal terms).
This is important because state budgets tend to be procyclical
and exacerbate macroeconomic swings; improved state budget
positions would reduce the need to raise taxes or cut spending
in a recession. State budget position results were not available
from the Moody’s model. The dollar amounts shown in Figure
3.11 represent, on average, 0.11 percent of GDP for the simula-
tion with the Fed’s rule in place and 0.12 percent of GDP with
the Fed’s rule turned off. From a consolidated federal-plus-state
budget position perspective, the improvement in state budgets
offset by about one-fifth the net budgetary effects reported in
Figure 3.9. If one uses the Fair model’s estimates of effects on
state budgets to proxy for the Moody’s model simulations, then
the net budgetary effect, on a consolidated basis, is an increase in
the deficit-to-GDP ratio of 0.45–0.76 percentage points across
all four simulations, with the most likely range being 0.45–0.6
percentage points.
26
For the lower bound estimate without debt
service, the most likely range for the increase in the deficit-to-
GDP ratio falls to 0.39–0.46 percentage points. From the analy-
sis in Appendix B of the budgetary impacts relative to current
levels, on a consolidated basis the deficit-to-GDP ratio increases
by even less: within a range of 0.17 to 0.25 percentage points
(this includes the federal governments debt service).
Conclusions from simulations
During the first five years, all four simulations are quite simi-
lar and consistent. The Moody’s model with the Fed’s interest
rate target rule turned on only diverges from the other three
simulations in the latter five years of the simulated period.
Interestingly, the differences between the two models did not
arise from the major theoretical difference between them—the
“Classical” long run in the Moody’s model that is not present in
the Fair model. The core difference was that the Moody’s model
is significantly more sensitive to small changes in interest rates
than the Fair model, as noted above several times. As the student
debt cancellation stimulates the economy, the Fed raises interest
rates by nearly the same amount in both the Fair model and the
Moody’s model; the effect in the Moody’s model is to slow the
economy significantly. However, given that both models show
very little inflationary impact from the cancellation—both in
absolute terms and in terms of macroeconomic significance—
it should not be unreasonable to expect that the Fed would
not react to the cancellation by raising rates, and therefore the
Moody’s simulations without the Fed’s reaction function would
be the more relevant ones. This is consistent with the fact that
the results of the two Fair model simulations are very much in
line with those of the Moody’s model with the Fed’s interest rate
target rule turned off.
Figure 3.11 Average Improvement in State Budget
Positions Resulting from Student Loan Cancellation
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Sour
ce: Authorscalculations
Fair Model
Fair Model No Fed
$ Billions
46 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Given this, the primary takeaways from the Fair model and
Moody’s simulations of the debt cancellation are the following
(these exclude the “Moody’s with Fed” results, except in the fifth
bullet point summarizing interest rate changes):
The most likely range for the total increase in real GDP (in
2016 dollars) is estimated to be between $861 billion and
$1,083 billion for the entire 10-year period (or $86 billion to
$108 billion per year, on average).
Unemployment rates could fall by about 0.22 to 0.36 percent-
age points on average over the entire period.
There could be significant macroeconomic improvements,
with real GDP rising (particularly early on), and peak addi-
tional job creation about 50 percent to 70 percent as large as
a typical year’s overall job creation in the 2010–15 expansion.
The Fair model suggests these effects peak about a year earlier
on average than in the Moody’s model.
Inflationary effects appear to be small and macroeconomi-
cally insignificant.
Interest rates rise modestly, if at all. The Fed raises rates 0.3–
0.5 percentage points early on in step with the economy’s
improvement, and then the increase relative to the baseline
values falls to 0.13 percentage points by the end of 2026.
Increases in longer-term rates peak in the range of 0.25–0.4
percentage points, mostly in a manner consistent with the
Fed’s approach to shorter-term rates (although the Moody’s
model suggests 0.2 to 0.25 percentage points of this increase
is due to government deficits). However, given that there is
effectively no inflationary impact from the cancellation, it is
highly questionable whether the Fed would or at least should
raise interest rates in the first place.
The cancellations impact on the federal government’s budget
is, on average, modest, with a deficit impact of 0.65 to 0.75
percent of GDP, which falls to between 0.59 and 0.61 percent
of GDP if the government is not in an overall deficit position
(either because it begins with a surplus when the cancellation
is implemented or the cost of the cancellation is offset) or
interest rates remain very low. Furthermore, the calculations
from Appendix B suggest that the more relevant estimate of
the average annual rise in the deficit ratio, relative to current
levels of the governments budget position and outstanding
liabilities, is much smaller still: between 0.29 and 0.37 percent
of GDP.
The cancellation improves state budget positions such that,
from the standpoint of a consolidated state-plus-federal
budget, the net increase in the (consolidated) budget deficit
is 0.10 to 0.12 percent of GDP lower than the increase for the
federal government alone.
Of course, as discussed earlier, there are many potential
benefits of debt cancellation that cannot be simulated in a mac-
roeconometric model. These simulations should therefore be
considered as providing estimates of a “subset of these poten-
tial benefits. The following section presents and explains some
of the benefits beyond the scope of these simulations.
Omitted Benefits and Costs of Student Debt
Cancellation
The macroeconomic results presented in this report summarize
the income and wealth effects of student debt cancellation but
cannot capture all of the potential advantages and disadvan-
tages of the program. Evidence supports a number of socioeco-
nomic benefits that have been omitted from the models here.
Despite their formal exclusion, this section provides context
for the additional benefits of student debt cancellation, from
increases in business formation, college attainment, household
formation, and credit scores, to reduced economic vulnerabil-
ity for some households. Additionally, the projected costs asso-
ciated with changes in future attitudes toward borrowing are
only partially incorporated into the model, in order to isolate
the effects of the cancellation from other policy changes. The
implications of a one-time student debt cancellation for moral
hazard are also considered below.
Small business formation
Starting a business requires access to capital and an appetite for
risk—two characteristics that may be inhibited by high student
debt levels. Small businesses in particular tend to depend on
financing from personal debt. Since student loan debt appears
as negative net worth on household balance sheets, borrowers
with high debt balances and monthly payments find it more
difficult to accumulate startup capital through saving or bor-
rowing. As a result, the growth of student loan debt is associated
with reductions in small business formation.
Recent research from the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia examined this relationship between the growth in
student loan debt and small business formation. Philadelphia
Federal Reserve researchers Ambrose, Cordell, and Ma (2015)
show that student loan debt reduces an individual’s ability to
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 47
save startup capital or access alternative forms of credit for busi-
ness formation. The authors estimate these trends at the county
level over the period 2000–10, while accounting for county-level
differences in demographic and risk factors. During the period
of study, student debt as a share of total personal debt rose
across all counties, with an average rise of 4.7 percentage points
(from 2.8 percent of total debt in 1999 to 7.5 percent in 2009)
and a standard deviation of 3.3 percent. The authors estimate
a 14.4 percent decline in small business formation associated
with an increase of one standard deviation of relative student
debt (that is, relative to total personal debt). These effects are
strongest among the smallest-sized category of business—those
with one to four employees—where personal credit is presumed
to be a larger portion of total business financing.
The negative relationship between student loan debt and
entrepreneurship identified by Ambrose, Cordell, and Ma
is supported by survey responses solicited by the Consumer
Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB). In 2013, the CFPB pub-
lished an analysis of detailed public comments on student loan
affordability (CFPB 2013). Individuals, small business coali-
tions, and advocacy groups identified student loan debt as a
barrier to accessing credit and debt payments as a diversion of
business startup and expansion funds. According to the report,
young entrepreneurs in particular are less able and less likely to
form businesses due to the accumulation of student loan debt.
College degree attainment
One principal benefit of pursuing postsecondary education,
and taking on student loans, is the education premium that
accompanies an advanced degree. This premium is only real-
ized if a degree is completed, but mounting debt makes degree
attainment more difficult for students facing financial con-
straints. The relationship between debt and college completion
is documented in several papers, with some consensus around
the finding that high levels of student debt reduce college com-
pletion while access to grant funding promotes enrollment and
persistence, leading to higher degree attainment.
Three articles drawing on the National Longitudinal Survey
of Youth identify a positive correlation between student debt
and college completion at lower levels of debt, turning nega-
tive at an inflection point around $10,000—well below the aver-
age debt level of borrowers. In the journal Social Forces, Dwyer,
McCloud, and Hodson (2012) find that this relationship holds
true across the income distribution but that the relationship is
stronger for students from the bottom 75 percent of earnings.
The same authors reproduce these findings in a 2013 article, and
find that while high debt reduces the chances of graduating for
both men and women, men are likely to drop out at lower levels
of debt (Dwyer, McCloud, and Hodson 2013). In the Journal of
Sociology and Social Welfare, Min Zhan (2014) shows that stu-
dent loan debt above $10,000 reduces college graduation even
after accounting for family assets.
High student debt as a share of total debt reduces an individual’s ability to access
alternative forms of credit for business formation. Small business formation declines 14.4
percent with an increase of one standard deviation of relative student debt.
Grant funding increases college attendance and reduces college dropout rates. A $1,000
increase in Pell Grants is associated with a 1.2 percent to 8.6 percent decrease in students
leaving college; $1000 in non-need-based grant aid increases college attendance by 3.6
percent.
A $1,000 increase in student debt is associated with a 2 percent decline in the likelihood
of first marriage among female degree-holders.
Student loan borrowers have lower credit scores, potentially leading to household credit
constraints and reduced consumption.
Households with student debt experienced greater reductions in net worth than
households with no student debt during the most recent recession. A $1 increase in
student loan debt in 2007 was associated with $0.87 less in net worth in 2009.
Table 3.1 Additional Benefits of Student Debt Cancellation
Predicted Effect
of Student Debt
Cancellation
Description Source
Increased small
business formation
Increased college
degree attainment
Increased household
formation
Higher credit scores
Reduced vulnerability
to economic shocks
Ambrose, Cordell, and Ma (2015)
Bettinger (2004)
Dynarski (2003)
Bozick and Estacion (2014)
Addo (2014)
Edmiston, Brooks, and Shepelwich (2013)
Li (2013)
Elliott and Nam (2013)
48 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
For predicting changes in college completion associated
with a student debt cancellation in the context of free or debt-
free college, it may be most useful to look at the relationship
between debt-free education financing and degree attainment.
Here two studies support a relationship between grant fund-
ing and college completion. In a 2003 article in the American
Economic Review, Susan Dynarski (2003) demonstrated that
the elimination of grant aid reduced college attendance among
the previously eligible population by more than one-third.
Dynarski found that the availability of grant aid increases both
attendance and completion, with an offer of $1,000 in funding
increasing the chance of attendance by 3.6 percentage points.
In a 2004 National Bureau of Economic Research study, author
Eric Bettinger (2004) performs both panel and cross-sectional
analysis on the relationship between need-based Pell Grants and
college completion. The panel data shows a strong negative cor-
relation between Pell Grant increases and drop-out rates, with
a $1,000 increase in Pell Grants associated with 6.4 percent to
8.6 percent decreases in students leaving college. The cross-
sectional analysis shows similar though smaller results, with 1.2
percent to 4 percent decreases in the likelihood of dropping out
associated with a $1,000 Pell Grant increase.
The cancellation plan would reduce the current debt bur-
den on those enrolled in school, and will likely increase the
rate of completion. Over a longer time horizon, this increase
in degree attainment will extend the positive effects of the can-
cellation by increasing the income and productivity of the US
labor force.
Household formation
Entering marriage and beginning a household is associated with
a range of socioeconomic benefits, including better health and
higher income, while household public goods and risk pool-
ing can be a means out of poverty (Schwartz 2005). Existing
research suggests that debt, including student debt, is associated
with a decreased probability of household formation. Recent
studies isolating the relationship between student debt and
marriage support this claim.
The impact of educational debt on decisions to marry is
observed by Bozick and Estacion (2014) using data from the
1993 Baccalaureate and Beyond Longitudinal Study. Using
a discrete-time hazard model, they find that the odds of first
marriage decline by 2 percent with an increase of $1,000 in
student loan borrowing among females in the first four years
after attaining a college degree. In Demography, Addo (2014)
produces similar results using the National Longitudinal Survey
of Youth.
Credit scores
Student loan borrowers in general exhibit lower credit scores
than the population overall (Edmiston, Brooks, and Shepelwich
2013). The New York Federal Reserves Brown and Caldwell
(2013) demonstrate that student loan borrowers ages 25 to 30
had Equifax risk scores 15 to 24 points below those of nonbor-
rowers in the years between 2008 and 2013. Researchers disagree
whether this divergence in credit ratings occurs due to higher
delinquency and default rates associated with unmanageable
student debt levels or due to increased lending to student bor-
rowers who already had low credit scores after the reform of
bankruptcy discharge laws that made it increasingly difficult
for borrowers who cannot make their student loan payments to
discharge the debt (Edmiston, Brooks, and Shepelwich 2013; Li
2013; Darolia and Ritter 2015). In either case, low credit scores
may reduce access to other forms of credit despite the higher
earning potential of college graduates.
Household vulnerability in business cycle downturns
Credit constraints, delayed household formation, lower net
worth, and debt service obligations can all be sources of eco-
nomic fragility associated with student debt. For these reasons,
student loan debt can have negative financial consequences for
individuals and families even when all payments are on time
and up to date. In a 2013 publication from the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis, authors Elliot and Nam (2013) investigate the
relationship between student debt and household economic
security. They use the Survey of Consumer Finances to mea-
sure the relationship between student debt and net worth dur-
ing periods of economic instability. Using the years 2007 and
2009 as reference points for the Great Recession, the authors
find that households carrying student debt faced greater losses
in net worth during the recession compared to similar house-
holds with no student debt. According to their research, each $1
increase in student loans for the median household in 2007 was
associated with lower net worth of $0.87 in 2009. The negative
relationship between student debt and net worth appeared con-
sistently, regardless of net worth quintile, but the largest relative
losses occurred among households at the bottom of the income
distribution.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 49
Moral hazard
The best context for student debt cancellation is one where a
high-quality college education is available to all students who
seek it without the need for debt financing. Without a change
to our current system of increasingly private responsibility for
funding higher education, households will continue to meet
the growing cost of a college degree by taking on debt, divert-
ing household resources from other types of investment and
consumption. The primary theoretical criticism of debt can-
cellation plans focuses on the reaccumulation of debt follow-
ing the cancellation, in particular the potential for problems of
moral hazard to arise. From this perspective, debt relief today
could change the incentives of future student debtors who may
increase borrowing with the expectation that the loans will
be forgiven, causing an even faster accumulation of debt and
increasing the negative consequences at the household, local,
and macroeconomic levels. The perverse incentives for unsus-
tainable borrowing in this scenario are the result of inappro-
priate policy institutions that absolve borrowers of their debts
while perpetuating the necessity of increasing debt. In order to
avoid problems of moral hazard, any restructuring of student
debt—including our debt cancellation proposal—should be
accompanied by strong and appropriate policies that enforce
the consequences of borrowing and address the market failures
that lead to undesirable social costs. In combination with debt
cancellation, publicly funded free or debt-free college would
provide the institutional reform necessary to avert the problem
of moral hazard.
Although complementary reform of higher education
financing should accompany a student debt cancellation, this
research is focused on the specific question of the impact of
total cancellation of current debts. It is not an attempt to study
the institutions necessary to frame a debt cancellation. Each
model in this report isolates the effects of debt cancellation. In
Moody’s structural macroeconomic model, the cancellation is
evaluated in the context of the Clinton Compact, a policy mak-
ing debt-free public college attainable for more than 80 per-
cent of households and largely eliminating the need for future
debt associated with a four-year college degree. The difference
between the modeled effects of debt-free college alone and
debt-free college in conjunction with a program of student debt
cancellation is the positive impact of debt cancellation in the
absence of moral hazard. In the Fair model scenario, student
debt reaccumulates beginning in the first quarter following the
cancellation. No complementary policy is incorporated into
the simulation. Each model imposes an institutional context in
which moral hazard problems do not arise in order to focus the
analysis on student debt cancellation.
50 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Conclusion
This report examines the context, implementation, and out-
comes of a program of complete student debt cancellation. We
find that student debt cancellation produces positive feedback
effects that improve several macroeconomic variables, including
GDP and job growth, while imposing only moderate increases
on the federal deficit and interest rates and no significant infla-
tionary pressure. These results support the continued inclusion
of bold proposals such as student debt cancellation in public
policy deliberations surrounding the future of higher education
in the United States. Our findings offer an essential contribu-
tion to this debate.
In Section 1, we review the trends in higher education costs,
public financing, and student debt. The increasing need for a
college degree to attain financial security drew more students
into higher education at the same time that public support for
education declined, prompting the growth of student debt to
record levels. Today, student loan debt presents a significantly
higher burden on household finances than ever before, with
implications for the entire economy. Many borrowers struggle
to make payments, while others forego important investment
opportunities such as homeownership and business forma-
tion. These limitations translate into lower consumption and
investment spending in the aggregate, leading to slower growth,
greater vulnerability to economic shocks, and the potential for
a higher education market failure. Complete cancellation of
outstanding student loans could reverse many of these negative
effects.
The possibility of enacting student debt cancellation is the
subject of Section 2, where we examine the current mechan-
ics of student lending and the balance sheet effects of a pro-
gram of debt cancellation. There are two key takeaways. First,
the new budgetary costs of cancelling the loans issued by the
Department of Education (ED) do not come in the form of for-
gone principal and interest payments on those loans—the sole
costs would be the continuation of debt service on the securities
originally issued by the Treasury to fund the ED loans. Second,
whether the cancellation is carried out by the federal govern-
ment or the Fed, the outcome is the same in terms of the finan-
cial positions of borrowers and the federal budget. There is no
budgetary “free lunch in having the Fed carry out the cancella-
tion. Under the Fed-initiated debt cancellation, however, there
are two possible options to reduce the effects on the govern-
ment balance sheet. One option is for the Fed to accommodate
the losses by purchasing new financial assets; the other option is
for the Fed to isolate losses from cancelling student loans from
the rest of its operating profits. Both options are quite contro-
versial, but would shield the federal government from the bal-
ance sheet effects of enacting the cancellation.
Finally, in Section 3 we forecast the effects of debt cancella-
tion over a 10-year horizon using two macroeconomic models,
the Fair model and Moody’s model. The results of these simula-
tions take into account the feedback effects of greater household
consumption and investment that are not captured in the bal-
ance sheet analysis in Section 2.
Our simulations show that student debt cancellation
results in an increase in GDP, a decrease in the average unem-
ployment rate, and little to no inflationary pressure over the
10-year horizon, while interest rates increase only modestly.
(Results reported here are from the two Fair model simula-
tions and the Moody’s simulation with the Fed’s interest rate
reaction function turned off.) Estimates for new GDP range
from $861 billion to $1,083 billion over the entire period, or
on average between $86 billion and $108 billion per year. This
increase is accompanied by new job creation that peaks at 1.18
to 1.55 million additional new jobs per year, or 50 to 70 percent
of the entire job creation for a typical year in the 2010–15 eco-
nomic expansion. Average unemployment rates over the period
are reduced by between 0.22 and 0.36 percentage points. The
predicted effects of the cancellation on inflation are negligible,
with a peak of 0.3 percentage points of additional inflation in
the Fair model and negative pressure on inflation in later years,
and no more than 0.09 percentage points of additional inflation
in the Moody’s model over the entire period. The simulations
suggest that the Federal Reserve raises target rates modestly in
the early years of the cancellation, adding 0.3 to 0.5 percentage
points to the rate, with lower effects in later years. The effect on
longer-term interest rates peaks at 0.25 to 0.4 percent. Finally,
government spending to repay privately held loans and the loss
of interest income from ED loans results in a larger budget defi-
cit for the federal government. The average effect of the cancel-
lation on the federal government’s net budget position ranges
between –0.65 and –0.75 percent of GDP per annum. However,
those figures assume all the foregone revenues from cancelling
the Department of Educations loans are incurred anew (see
Appendix B). The more relevant estimate of these impacts—
relative to current levels of deficits and the national debt—is a
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 51
range of –0.29 to –0.37 percent of GDP. Finally, the Fair model
shows an improvement in state budget positions (these effects
were not available in the Moody’s simulations).
Our analysis suggests that debt cancellation is a feasible
program that would increase economic activity in the short
run with moderate consequences on the federal deficit. These
consequences should be balanced against the important social
gains available from greater investment in higher education and
the relief of debt as educators, advocates, borrowers, and poli-
cymakers continue to debate the path forward for US higher
education.
52 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Appendix A: Simulation Data Series
The macroeconomic simulations generate a $1.406 trillion
one-time increase in net wealth of the household sector in the
first quarter of 2017. The 10-year horizon for the government’s
reduction in revenues, payments to private investors, and debt
service payments for the Department of Education (ED) and
privately owned loans are presented in Appendix Tables A.1,
A.2, A.3, and A.4. Table A.1 shows the estimated principal
reduction of the different types of loans in the absence of debt
cancellation for the purposes of determining (1) the amount of
revenue the government does not receive but would have with-
out the cancellation and (2) the debt service payments to pri-
vate investors that the federal government subsequently bears.
Table A.2 presents the estimated debt service for loans owned by
the ED. These are calculated as the pay down in principal each
quarter (the change in the respective rows in Table A.1) plus
interest (interest rate multiplied by principal owed at the end of
Table A.1 Assumed Pay Down of Student Loan Debt in the Absence of Student Debt Cancellation ($ billions)
Owned by ED Privately Owned, Government-Guaranteed Privately Owned, Not Government-Guaranteed
Counterfactual for Debt Owed Counterfactual for Debt Owed Counterfactual for Debt Owed
at End of Quarter at End of Quarter at End of Quarter
End of 2016 1024.61 276.95 105.44
2017Q1 998.64 260.66 102.87
2017Q2 973.68 244.37 100.30
2017Q3 948.71 228.08 97.72
2017Q4 923.74 211.79 95.15
2018Q1 898.78 195.50 92.58
2018Q2 873.81 179.20 90.01
2018Q3 848.85 162.91 87.44
2018Q4 823.88 146.62 84.87
2019Q1 798.91 130.33 82.29
2019Q2 773.95 114.04 79.72
2019Q3 748.98 97.75 77.15
2019Q4 724.02 81.46 74.58
2020Q1 699.05 65.17 72.01
2020Q2 674.08 48.87 69.44
2020Q3 649.12 32.58 66.86
2020Q4 624.15 16.29 64.29
2021Q1 599.18 0.00 61.72
2021Q2 574.22 0.00 59.15
2021Q3 549.25 0.00 56.58
2021Q4 524.29 0.00 54.01
2022Q1 499.32 0.00 51.43
2022Q2 474.35 0.00 48.86
2022Q3 449.39 0.00 46.29
2022Q4 424.42 0.00 43.72
2023Q1 399.46 0.00 41.15
2023Q2 374.49 0.00 38.58
2023Q3 349.52 0.00 36.00
2023Q4 324.56 0.00 33.43
2024Q1 299.59 0.00 30.86
2024Q2 274.63 0.00 28.29
2024Q3 249.66 0.00 25.72
2024Q4 224.69 0.00 23.15
2025Q1 199.73 0.00 20.57
2025Q2 174.76 0.00 18.00
2025Q3 149.80 0.00 15.43
2025Q4 124.83 0.00 12.86
2026Q1 99.86 0.00 10.29
2026Q2 74.90 0.00 7.72
2026Q3 49.93 0.00 5.14
2026Q4 24.97 0.00 2.57
Source: Authors’ calculations
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 53
the previous quarter). The debt service for the ED-owned loans
is the estimated reduction in government revenue as a result of
the cancellation. Table A.3 is similar to Table A.2, but instead
shows debt service for student loans owned by the private sector
without government insurance; this is an assumed outlay in the
simulations, as the government takes on these payments. Table
A.4 is the debt service for the privately owned, government-
guaranteed loans, which are also borne by the government in
the cancellation but are assumed to be paid down completely
by the end of 2020. Interest on these loans is calculated as the
outstanding principal from the previous quarter multiplied by
the short-term rate from the previous quarter plus the markup
(currently 2.3 percent), and then divided by four for quarterly
compounding. As noted above, the short-term interest rate is
determined within the simulations. As an example only, Table
A.4 uses the baseline level of the T-Bill rate from the Fair model
forecasts (that is, the simulated model without the debt cancel-
lation incorporated).
Government Owned
Interest Rate = 4.6%
Counterfactual Debt Service ($ billions)
2017Q1 36.74
2017Q2 36.16
2017Q3 35.88
2017Q4 35.59
2018Q1 35.30
2018Q2 35.01
2018Q3 34.73
2018Q4 34.44
2019Q1 34.15
2019Q2 33.87
2019Q3 33.58
2019Q4 33.29
2020Q1 33.01
2020Q2 32.72
2020Q3 32.43
2020Q4 32.14
2021Q1 31.86
2021Q2 31.57
2021Q3 31.28
2021Q4 31.00
2022Q1 30.71
2022Q2 30.42
2022Q3 30.13
2022Q4 29.85
2023Q1 29.56
2023Q2 29.27
2023Q3 28.99
2023Q4 28.70
2024Q1 28.41
2024Q2 28.12
2024Q3 27.84
2024Q4 27.55
2025Q1 27.26
2025Q2 26.98
2025Q3 26.69
2025Q4 26.40
2026Q1 26.11
2026Q2 25.83
2026Q3 25.54
2026Q4 25.25
Table A.2 Assumed Debt Service Payments Not Received
after Cancellation of Student Loans Owned by the
Department of Education ($ billions)
Source: Authors’ calculations
Table A.3 Assumed Debt Service Payment Outlays for the
Government after Cancellation of Student Loans Owned by
the Private Sector and Not Government-Guaranteed
($ billions)
Privately Owned, No Government Insurance
Interest Rate = 10%
Counterfactual Debt Service ($ billions)
2017Q1 5.21
2017Q2 5.14
2017Q3 5.08
2017Q4 5.01
2018Q1 4.95
2018Q2 4.89
2018Q3 4.82
2018Q4 4.76
2019Q1 4.69
2019Q2 4.63
2019Q3 4.56
2019Q4 4.50
2020Q1 4.44
2020Q2 4.37
2020Q3 4.31
2020Q4 4.24
2021Q1 4.18
2021Q2 4.11
2021Q3 4.05
2021Q4 3.99
2022Q1 3.92
2022Q2 3.86
2022Q3 3.79
2022Q4 3.73
2023Q1 3.66
2023Q2 3.60
2023Q3 3.54
2023Q4 3.47
2024Q1 3.41
2024Q2 3.34
2024Q3 3.28
2024Q4 3.21
2025Q1 3.15
2025Q2 3.09
2025Q3 3.02
2025Q4 2.96
2026Q1 2.89
2026Q2 2.83
2026Q3 2.76
2026Q4 2.70
Source: Authors’ calculations
54 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Table A.4 Assumed Debt Service Payment Outlays for the Government after Cancellation of Government-Guaranteed
Student Loans Owned by the Private Sector ($ billions)
Privately Owned, Government-Guaranteed
Interest Rate = Previous Quarter’s Fed Funds Rate + 2.3%
Principal Remaining at (Example) Fair Model Base Interest Rate Counterfactual
End of Previous Quarter T-Bill Rate from Markup (%) Debt Service
($ billions) Previous Quarter (%) ($ billions)
2017Q1 260.66 0.31 2.30 18.10
2017Q2 244.37 0.25 2.30 17.95
2017Q3 228.08 0.27 2.30 17.86
2017Q4 211.79 0.33 2.30 17.79
2018Q1 195.50 0.40 2.30 17.72
2018Q2 179.20 0.48 2.30 17.65
2018Q3 162.91 0.59 2.30 17.59
2018Q4 146.62 0.72 2.30 17.52
2019Q1 130.33 0.85 2.30 17.45
2019Q2 114.04 0.98 2.30 17.36
2019Q3 97.75 1.12 2.30 17.27
2019Q4 81.46 1.25 2.30 17.16
2020Q1 65.17 1.39 2.30 17.04
2020Q2 48.87 1.53 2.30 16.92
2020Q3 32.58 1.67 2.30 16.78
2020Q4 16.29 1.81 2.30 16.63
2021Q1 0.00 1.95 2.30 24.33
Source: Authors’ calculations
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 55
Appendix B: Department of
Education Loans and the Budget
Deficit
Macroeconometric simulations by nature compare a policy or
change in one or more variables to a baseline case. The simula-
tions presented in this report likewise compare the student debt
cancellation to the baseline case of no student debt cancellation.
However, in Section 2 of the report, it is shown that for the can-
cellation of the Department of Educations (ED’s) loans there
is a difference between comparing the change in government
liabilities relative to no cancellation and the actual increase in
liabilities that would occur. This is because the ED’s loans were
previously funded via issuance of government securities; as a
result, only the interest due on these securities is financed by
new increases in government securities outstanding. There is no
increase in government liabilities from cancellation of the princi-
pal on the ED’s loans. Rather, the principal amount of the loans,
funded originally by previously issued securities, is rolled over.
The fundamental difference is that the baseline case in
the simulations assumes the ED’s loans are paid down, which
would in theory enable retiring the securities previously issued
to fund the EDs loans. Relative to this assumed baseline, student
debt cancellation raises the government deficit and increases
the amount of government securities issued by the combined
amount of the principal and interest on the EDs loans. This
larger deficit is then compounded as it further raises future debt
service on the national debt, raising future deficits as well. While
the simulation results reported are “correct” in the sense that
they report changes from the baseline, they also significantly
overstate the actual, absolute increases in the national debt—
and thus also the actual, annual deficits—that would result
from student debt cancellation relative to their current levels.
The purpose of this section is to provide some understanding
of the size of this overstatement.
To generate an estimate of the actual deficit impact of stu-
dent debt cancellation relative to current levels, the first step
is to estimate the effect of the cancellation of the ED’s loans.
Table B.1 presents the Federal Reserve’s interest rate targets
in the three core simulations: the Fair model, the Fair model
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 0.49% 0.31% 2.03%
2018 1.15% 0.66% 3.69%
2019 1.71% 1.18% 3.87%
2020 2.17% 1.74% 3.75%
2021 2.61% 2.29% 3.78%
2022 3.07% 2.85% 3.85%
2023 3.60% 3.40% 3.85%
2024 4.17% 3.97% 3.81%
2025 4.76% 4.57% 3.78%
2026 5.33% 5.14% 3.78%
Table B.1 Federal Reserves Interest Rate Target in the
Student Debt Cancellation Simulations
Source: Authors’ calculations
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 5.05 3.20 20.77
2018 11.84 6.79 38.52
2019 17.75 12.24 41.87
2020 22.94 18.17 42.18
2021 28.21 24.38 44.08
2022 34.06 30.98 46.67
2023 41.15 38.06 48.40
2024 49.36 45.95 49.72
2025 58.74 54.94 51.27
2026 68.88 64.70 53.18
Total 337.99 299.40 436.66
Table B.2 Annual Interest Cost for Securities Issued to
Fund Department of Education Loans in the Student Debt
Cancellation Simulations ($ billions)
Source: Authors’ calculations
2017 146.79 243.70 60.24%
2018 141.79 236.90 59.85%
2019 137.08 229.38 59.76%
2020 132.37 221.05 59.88%
2021 127.66 144.14 88.57%
2022 122.96 138.38 88.86%
2023 118.25 132.61 89.17%
2024 113.54 126.85 89.51%
2025 108.83 121.09 89.88%
2026 104.12 115.32 90.29%
Totals 1253.45 1709.48 73.32%
Table B.3 Data Series Estimates from Simulations for
Department of Education Loans and Total Debt Cancellation
($ billions)
Source: Authors’ calculations
Total Direct Spending
Increases/Revenue Losses
Due to Cancellation of All
Student Loans
(B)
Foregone Principal
and Interest on
ED’s Loans
(A) (A) / (B)
56 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
If one makes the (admittedly fairly crude but not altogether
unreasonable) assumption that the relative size of the direct
revenue/spending effect from cancelling the EDs loans with
respect to the total for cancelling all student loans is equal to
its contribution to the annual deficit, then an alternative deficit
estimate can be made that is more appropriate as a change from
current levels. Note that the more similar the multiplier effects
from cancelling the different types of student loans are, the more
reasonable this assumption is. Since all of the cancellations are
ultimately affecting the economy via the household sector, mul-
tiplier effects, at least within these models, would seem fairly
consistent across different loan types. Table B.4 presents the
increases in annual budget deficits from baseline forecast results
in each simulation. Table B.5 multiplies the entries in Table B.4
by the third column of Table B.3. In other words, Table B.5 can
serve as an estimate of how much the assumed loss of revenues
from cancelling the ED’s loans affected the government’s budget
in the simulations.
To calculate an estimate of the actual effect of cancelling the
ED’s loans on the deficit, relative to current levels, subtract the
entries in Table B.5 from the entries in Table B.4, then add the
entries in Table B.2. This simply replaces the effect of the ED’s
loans on the deficit in Table B.4 with the estimates of debt ser-
vice on the securities issued to fund the ED’s loans in Table B.2
in calculating the deficit. If anything, this would be an overes-
timate, because there are no feedback effects assumed from the
spending in Table B.2 that might reduce the deficit. Though the
multiplier effects of government debt service on the economy
are likely small, there are some offsets to the spending’s effect on
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 212.84 210.63 227.67
2018 189.19 175.16 169.88
2019 198.77 171.47 187.42
2020 210.54 176.97 212.11
2021 156.39 123.08 158.74
2022 162.08 132.56 165.56
2023 158.91 132.66 160.26
2024 155.14 129.53 157.13
2025 153.11 126.37 158.88
2026 152.71 124.32 164.16
Totals 1749.69 1502.76 1761.86
Average 174.97 150.28 176.19
Table B.4 Increases in Annual Budget Deficits from
Baseline Forecasts in the Student Debt Cancellation
Simulations ($ billions)
Source: Authors’ calculations
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 128.20 126.87 137.13
2018 113.23 104.83 101.67
2019 118.78 102.47 112.01
2020 126.08 105.97 127.02
2021 138.51 109.01 140.59
2022 144.01 117.78 147.11
2023 141.69 118.28 142.90
2024 138.86 115.93 140.64
2025 137.61 113.58 142.80
2026 137.87 112.24 148.21
Totals 1324.89 1127.02 1340.14
Table B.5 Estimated Deficit Impact of Cancellation of
Department of Education Loans in the Student Debt
Cancellation Simulations ($ billions)
Source: Authors’ calculations
without the Fed’s rule in effect, and the Moody’s model without
the Fed’s rule in effect. These interest rates would be applied
to the rolling over of the securities previously issued to fund
the ED’s loans. As Section 2 of this report explains, this debt
service cost is the actual cost to the government of cancelling
the ED’s loans relative to current spending levels. To estimate
this cost, the interest rates in Table B.1 can be applied to the
value of the outstanding ED loans at the beginning of the simu-
lations ($1.024 trillion) that will subsequently be cancelled. As
the debt is rolled over each period and the interest rates also rise
throughout the simulations duration, the cost rises. Table B.2
presents these annual costs for each simulation, which would
be estimates of the direct costs to the government of the cancel-
lation of the ED’s loans, relative to current levels. The final row
sums up each column.
Because the simulations instead presented a counterfac-
tual, the full revenue loss from foregone interest and principal
payments were assumed to be the direct costs of cancelling the
ED’s loans. From the data series estimates of the debt cancella-
tion used in the simulations, the principal and interest foregone
on the ED loans make up roughly 60 percent of the total direct
spending/direct revenue loss from the cancellation during the
2017–20 period (i.e., the first four years), and roughly 90 percent
during the 2021–26 period. The figures used in the simulation
are shown in Table B.3. The first column is estimated foregone
principal and interest from cancelling the ED’s loans. The sec-
ond column is the total estimated direct spending increases and
revenue losses from the cancellation of all student loans. The
third column is the first column divided by the second column.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 57
the deficit, at the very least through taxation of interest in cer-
tain cases. Table B.6 presents the new estimates of government
deficits from student debt cancellation.
The differences between Table B.4 (from the simulation)
and Table B.6 (the new, adjusted deficits) are significant. From
the totals for each, the average annual deficit in the simulations
relative to baseline levels in Table B.4 ranges from $150 billion
to $176 billion. For the adjusted deficits in Table B.6, the annual
average ranges from $68 billion to $86 billion, or about one-
half as large. Tables B.7 and B.8 present the same data as a per-
cent of nominal GDP generated in the respective simulations.
Here again, the difference is significant, with simulation deficit
impacts ranging between 0.65 and 0.75 percent of GDP, and
deficit impacts relative to current levels ranging between 0.29
and 0.37 percent of GDP.
Which of the two sets of estimates is correct”? They both
are. For the purpose of a counterfactual, as is standard for mac-
roeconometric simulations, the larger deficit impacts in Tables
B.5 and B.7 are the “correct” estimates of differences from
“baseline levels” that assume no cancellation. But for the pur-
pose of estimating actual deficit and national debt impacts rela-
tive to their current levels, the smaller estimates in Tables B.6
and B.8 are correct. In other words, in the event of a student
debt cancellation similar to the one simulated in this report, if
one assumes the results from these three simulations are reason-
able estimates, the range of increases in total government defi-
cits over the next 10 years should be expected to be $675 billion
to $858 billion, not $1,127 billion to $1,340 billion.
A final reason for considering the smaller estimates in
Tables B.6 and B.8 as the more relevant ones is that the baseline
case in the simulations assumes that the loans are paid down
in a timely manner in the absence of the cancellation. But it
is well-known that student loans have a high rate of repay-
ment difficulties relative to many other types of loans, and that
there are significant costs to recouping past-due payments. For
the purposes here, the degree to which student loans become
increasingly problematic for borrowers to service in the future
reduces the relative cost of student loan cancellation now. That
is, as more difficulties are encountered in the future collecting
student loan payments, the baseline assumption that loans are
repaid should be revised to reflect this, and the cost of cancella-
tion relative to this baseline would thereby decline.
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 89.69 86.95 111.30
2018 87.80 77.11 106.73
2019 97.73 81.24 117.29
2020 107.40 89.16 127.27
2021 46.08 38.44 62.22
2022 52.12 45.75 65.12
2023 58.36 52.43 65.76
2024 65.64 59.54 66.21
2025 74.24 67.74 67.35
2026 83.71 76.78 69.13
Totals 762.78 675.13 858.37
Average 76.28 67.51 85.84
Table B.6 Estimated Deficit Impact of Student Debt
Cancellation Relative to Current Levels ($ billions)
Source: Authors’ calculations
Table B.7 Increases in Annual Budget Deficits from Baseline
Forecasts in the Student Debt Cancellation Simulations as a
Percent of GDP
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 1.11% 1.09% 1.16%
2018 0.93% 0.86% 0.82%
2019 0.94% 0.80% 0.86%
2020 0.95% 0.79% 0.94%
2021 0.67% 0.53% 0.68%
2022 0.66% 0.54% 0.68%
2023 0.62% 0.52% 0.63%
2024 0.57% 0.48% 0.60%
2025 0.53% 0.44% 0.58%
2026 0.50% 0.41% 0.58%
Average 0.75% 0.65% 0.75%
Source: Authors’ calculations
Table B.8 Estimated Deficit Impact of Student Debt
Cancellation Relative to Current Levels as a Percent of GDP
Fair Model Fair Model No Fed Moody’s No Fed
2017 0.47% 0.45% 0.57%
2018 0.43% 0.38% 0.51%
2019 0.46% 0.38% 0.54%
2020 0.48% 0.40% 0.57%
2021 0.20% 0.16% 0.27%
2022 0.21% 0.19% 0.27%
2023 0.23% 0.20% 0.26%
2024 0.24% 0.22% 0.25%
2025 0.26% 0.24% 0.25%
2026 0.28% 0.25% 0.24%
Average 0.33% 0.29% 0.37%
Source: Authors’ calculations
58 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Appendix C: Digression on the
Fed’s Operations
The Fed targets the federal funds rate in the federal funds mar-
ket. In the federal funds market, (mostly) banks borrow and lend
reserve balances held in their accounts at the Fed. Individual
banks use reserve balances to settle payments and to meet reserve
requirements, and their demand for reserve balances is known
to be quite interest-insensitive—banks short of reserve balances
need them and banks with unwanted excess have little use for
them. Because reserve balances in the aggregate are a liability of
the Fed, banks in the aggregate cannot affect the quantity cir-
culating with their trading in the federal funds market, which
simply moves balances from one bank to another. In order to
achieve its target rate, the Fed traditionally adjusted reserve bal-
ances on a daily basis—to offset a deficiency or surplus relative
to banks demand for them at the Fed’s target rate—through
repurchase agreements (short-term, securitized loans to securi-
ties dealers, where the collateral was usually a Treasury-issued
security). The Fed’s operations were thus “accommodative” to
banks’ demand for reserve balances.
A simple model of the federal funds market under “nor-
mal” conditions is built in the next few figures.
27
Figure C.1
shows a standard demand curve for reserve balances in the
federal funds market. The vertical axis is the federal funds rate
and the horizontal axis is for reserve balances. There are three
interest rates—the federal funds rate target the Fed attempts to
i
fedfunds
*
i
penalty
i
fedfunds
RB
D
RB
i
IOR
Figure C.1 Demand for Reserve Balances in the Federal
F
unds Market
Figure C.2 Supply and Demand for Reserve Balances in the
“N
ormal” Federal Funds Market
RB*
i
fedfunds
*
i
penalty
i
fedfunds
RB
D
RB
i
IOR
S
RB
achieve in the federal funds market (i
fedfunds
*), the penalty rate the
Fed charges banks to borrow from their regional Fed bank rather
than from other banks in the federal funds market (i
penalty
), and
the rate the Fed pays banks for reserve balances held overnight
(i
IOR
). The demand curve for reserve balances (D
RB
) is nearly
vertical, with a bit of a downward slope, but becomes horizontal
at i
IOR
. The nearly vertical portion of D
RB
is because banks have
a particular amount of reserve balances they desire to hold in
order to settle payments and meet reserve requirements, and
they have little interest in holding much more or less than this
amount.
28
The horizontal portion is because i
IOR
becomes a
price floor for the federal funds rate if the Fed provides reserve
balances beyond the amount banks reasonably would hold to
meet reserve requirements and settle payments.
Figure C.2 shows a general model of the federal funds
market with both D
RB
from Figure C.1 and a supply curve for
reserve balances (S
RB
). The S
RB
schedule is vertical and then
kinks to become horizontal at i
penalty
. The vertical region repre-
sents the fact that it is the Fed that adjusts the aggregate quantity
of reserve balances—while banks can borrow/lend reserve bal-
ances among themselves, or send/receive payments in reserve
balances, these shift reserve balances around but do not change
the aggregate quantity. As all reserve accounts lie on the Fed’s
balance sheet, only an offsetting change to the Fed’s balance
sheet (such as a purchase of securities or a loan to a bank) can
alter the aggregate quantity of reserve balances. The horizontal
region of S
RB
represents the Fed’s standing facility, also called
the discount window” at the regional Federal Reserve Banks.
At the discount window, the Fed will lend to banks at i
penalty
,
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 59
accommodate shifts in D
RB
at the target federal funds rate) and
offsetting” (offsetting changes to the Fed’s balance sheet incon-
sistent with the quantity of reserve balances banks desire at the
Fed’s target federal funds rate).
Since Fall 2008, the Fed has left the quantity of reserve bal-
ances well beyond any level that would be consistent with the
downward sloping portion of D
RB
, rising from around $20 billion
prior to the financial crisis to about $800 billion later in 2008,
and then rising again through successive rounds of quantitative
easing to its current level of around $2.5 trillion. Essentially, this
leaves the quantity of reserve balances in the lower horizontal
portion of D
RB
consistent with i
IOR
. Consequently, the Fed has set
its target rate roughly equal to i
IOR
since late 2008, as discussed
above. Figure C.3 provides a simple illustration of the post-2008
federal funds market, where the Fed has pushed reserve balances
well beyond RB* (from Figure C.2) out to RB
QE
, thereby set-
ting its target rate equal to i
IOR
, as noted above. Again, this is
basic supply and demand analysis—pushing a supply curve well
beyond a demand curve reduces the price either to zero or to a
price floor set to keep the price from falling to zero.
It is well-known that the Fed’s target rate since late 2008
has actually been below i
IOR
because some nonbank entities
with reserve accounts do not earn interest—such as the Federal
Home Loan Banks, for instance—and must search for an inter-
est-bearing opportunity to invest their reserve balances. Given
the large quantity of excess reserve balances circulating, and
thus the dearth of competition among banks to borrow more
of them, these nonbank entities regularly find opportunities to
invest their reserve balances at banks only at rates below i
IOR
.
Consequently, prior to December 2015, while the Fed had i
IOR
Figure C.4 Corridor of Interest on Reserve Balances and
Re
verse Repurchase Agreement Rates
i
IOR
i
penalty
i
fedfunds
RB
QE
D
RB
S
RB
i
RRP
i
fedfunds
*
which effectively places a ceiling on how high i
fedfunds
can rise.
29
From Figure C.2, the combination of D
RB
and S
RB
presents a
general picture of the federal funds market where i
penalty
and
i
IOR
set a ceiling and a floor, respectively, on how high or low
i
fedfunds
can move. The difference between these two rates is fre-
quently referred to as a “corridor” within which i
fedfunds
* would
be expected to settle (in normal” times) as the Fed shifted the
vertical portion of S
RB
to intersect the nearly vertical portion of
D
RB
at its target rate.
It is clear from Figure C.2 that if the Fed grows reserve
balances much beyond RB*, the federal funds rate will fall to
i
IOR
. This would mean that the Fed had set a de facto interest
rate target at i
IOR
. Similarly, if the Fed were to reduce reserve bal-
ances, the federal funds rate would rather quickly rise to i
penalty
,
at which point the Fed would provide the reserve balances
through its standing facilities at the regional Fed banks until
the total quantity of reserve balances circulating equaled the
quantity banks desired to hold at i
penalty
. The Fed would then
have set a de facto target rate equal to i
penalty
.
30
The importance
of this reality—which is essentially basic supply and demand
analysis—comes from coupling it with an understanding of the
Fed’s balance sheet. Changes to the Fed’s balance sheet that are
not directly under the Fed’s control—changes in the balance of
the Treasury’s account or banks purchasing vault cash from the
Fed using balances in their reserve accounts, for instance—alter
the quantity of reserve balances circulating. Given the fairly
vertical slope of D
RB
between i
penalty
and i
IOR
, the Fed must off-
set these changes in order to achieve its target rate. In other
words, the Fed’s operations under “normal” circumstances are
accommodative (altering the quantity of reserve balances to
Figure C.3 Simple Model of the Federal Funds Market with
a Large Ex
cess of Reserve Balances as a Result of
Quantitativ
e Easing
i
fedfunds
* = i
IOR
i
penalty
i
fedfunds
RB
QE
D
RB
S
RB
.
60 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
set at 0.25 percent, the actual level of i
fedfunds
and thus i
fedfunds
*
fluctuated between zero and 0.25 percent, usually settling near
the midpoint between the two. When the Fed raised i
IOR
to 0.5
percent in late 2015 (from the earlier level of 0.25 percent), it
also instituted a reverse repurchase agreement (RRP) opportu-
nity. The opportunity was made available to a number of non-
bank financial institutions at 0.25 percent—including, but not
limited to, those with reserve accounts not earning interest on
reserve balances—in order to ensure that the federal funds rate
did not fall below that level. In other words, there is another cor-
ridor, which exists between i
IOR
and i
RRP
(the rate the Fed pays to
nonbanks investing in its RRPs). Figure C.4 shows the federal
funds market with the lower corridor between i
IOR
and i
RRP
, the
range (instead of a specific rate) the Fed has targeted for i
fedfunds
*.
The horizontal region of D
RB
has dipped below i
IOR
(since banks
have so many excess reserve balances they will not offer i
IOR
to
nonbank entities investing their reserve balances) but remains
above i
RRP
(since nonbank entities can now earn i
RRP
from the
Fed if banks do not offer at least that much).
31
As the Fed con-
tinues to raise the federal funds rate target thereafter, it does so
by simply announcing increases in both i
IOR
and i
RRP
. Overall, the
earlier analysis applies: if the Fed is going to oversupply the bank-
ing system with large quantities of excess reserve balances beyond
the levels banks would desire to hold at i
fedfunds
*, it will have to pay
interest on reserve balances, interest on RRPs, or interest on some
other liability it might issue (such as issuing its own securities or
time deposits) in order to achieve a positive i
fedfunds
*.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 61
Notes
1. The authors wish to express their appreciation to Joseph
Ballegeer for research assistance and to Mark Zandi, Chris
Lafakis, and Moody’s for generously sharing their time and
expertise with the Moody’s US Macroeconomic Model. We
also wish to thank Mary Green Swig and Steven L. Swig for
generous research support.
2. The simulation results summarized here incorporate two
Fair model simulations (with and without the Federal
Reserves interest rate target rule in effect) and one Moody’s
model simulation (without the Federal Reserve’s interest
rate target rule in effect). The exception is in the discussion
of the effect on interest rates, in which the largest effects
reported are from the Moody’s simulation with the Federal
Reserves interest rate target in effect. The simulation sec-
tion of this report (Section 3) discusses the rationale for
viewing these three as the most representative of the simu-
lation results.
3. For racial wealth and income gaps, see Emmons and Neoth
(2015).
4. The authors adjust household income and labor earnings
quintiles for the age distribution of student loan borrowers.
5. This calculation is based on the reported thresholds for
the quintiles. The greater the degree of inequality within
the top quintile, the more the 50 percent estimate from
thresholds underestimates the true income share of the top
quintile. Note that the World Wealth and Incomes Database
(WWID) computes that the income share of the top decile
was approximately 50 percent in 2015. The universe of all
tax units reported in WWID is richer than just the age-
adjusted sample used by Looney and Yannelis, since those
with student debt tend to be younger than the population
as a whole, but nonetheless, it is likely that the top quintile
of households even in the Looney and Yannelis data earns
more than 50 percent of total income.
6 For an overview, see Goldin and Katz (2010).
7. Accessed on July 20, 2016 from https://studentaid.ed.gov/
sa/about/data-center/student/portfolio
8. See, for instance, GAO (2014, 2001).
9. The Fed annually credits its profits to the Treasury’s account
after paying dividends on member banks’ investment
into Federal Reserve capital (“paid-in capital”) and any
investments into its own “surplus capital account. As of
December 2015, the Fed now pays a dividend of 6 per-
cent to those member institutions with less than $10 bil-
lion in consolidated assets and the lesser of 6 percent or
the high yield from the most recent 10-year Treasury note
auction, all as prescribed in the Fixing Americas Surface
Transportation Act (FAST Act). Prior to the FAST Act, the
Fed paid a 6 percent dividend on invested capital to all
member institutions based on their investment. Member
institutions’ investments are required by the Federal
Reserve Act; a member banks investment is based upon the
size of its own capital, and thus is regularly increased or
decreased in kind. Prior to the FAST Act, the Fed’s surplus
capital (that is, retained earnings) was maintained at a level
equal to its paid-in capital from member banks. However,
the FAST Act limited the Fed’s paid-in capital to $10 billion.
This resulted in a transfer from the Fed’s capital account to
the Treasury’s account of $19.3 billion in December 2015
in order to reduce its surplus capital to the legally man-
dated level. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System (2016). For more on the Fed’s surplus capital, see
Goodfriend (2014).
10. See Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(2016) for more information on the Fed’s remittances to
the Treasury, which, according to the press release, have
totaled $679.4 billion since 2006.
11. As with the earlier analysis of the federal government pur-
chasing the private loans, the analysis changes very little if
it is assumed the Fed pays a higher market price such that
the investors receive a capital gain, but there are additional
steps for explaining that scenario that unnecessarily com-
plicate an already detailed discussion.
12. The analysis in this section relies on the insights of a forth-
coming working paper by Raúl Carrillo, Rohan Grey, Robert
Hockett, and Nathan Tankus. The draft version is entitled
“The Legality of Student Loan Purchase and Forgiveness by
the Federal Reserve.
13. Simulations using the Moody’s model were facilitated by
Chris Lafakis and Mark Zandi at Moody’s.
14. Ray Fair’s website is https://fairmodel.econ.yale.edu. See
also Fair (2015, 2013, 2004).
15. See Fair (2004, 2013) for a full description of statistical tests
applied to the Fair model.
62 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
16. See Fair (2000). A draft version was published earlier on
his website, along with an interactive page that enabled the
user to determine how overvalued the market was.
17. As the sections on the mechanics of the student debt can-
cellation demonstrate using T-accounts, there is no double
counting involved in incorporating both an instantaneous
net wealth effect from cancellation and an income effect
over the following 10 years from cancelled debt service.
Both would actually occur.
18. The 10 percent assumption is an assumed average from fig-
ures shown on pp. 12–14 in CFPB (2012).
19. The baseline used for the Moody’s model is a bit more com-
plicated. As noted above, the Moody’s model was used for
simulating the economic proposals of the two candidates
for US President in 2016. For the simulation of Secretary
Clintons proposals, this included her College Compact”
proposal for reduced college tuition expenses. For the
Moody’s simulations in this report, the baseline reported is
the normal baseline forecast for the Moody’s model during
2017–26 with Secretary Clintons “College Compact” pro-
posal added to it. In other words, one might consider the
standard Moody’s baseline forecast as a “baseline 1” and a
“baseline 2, which is equal to “baseline 1” plus the Clinton
“Campus Compact” proposal. The Moody’s simulations in
this report use “baseline 2” as their baseline. Because the
Moody’s model is structural, there is no difference between
simulating the student debt cancellation starting from
“baseline 1” or “baseline 2. The differences between either
baseline and the subsequent addition of the student debt
cancellation will be the same. Consequently, the appropri-
ate interpretation of the results from either model is the
macroeconomic impact of an initial increase in household
net financial wealth that falls slowly over time, as in Table
A.1, combined with reduced revenue and increased outlays
by the federal government shown in Tables A.2, A.3, and
A.4. (Secretary Clintons proposed “College Compact” is
explained here: https://www.hillaryclinton.com/briefing/
factsheets/2015/08/10/college-compact-costs/)
20. Both models currently use 2009 as the base year for infla-
tion calculations—the year in which nominal and real GDP
are equal, and thus the price level using the GDP deflator
is set to 1. Using 2016 as the base year is more intuitive
here, particularly given simulations through 2026. The
method for converting a 2009 base year to a 2016 base year
is straightforward: divide the GDP deflator in each year of
the simulation period (2017–26) by the respective model’s
GDP deflator in 2016. The GDP deflator at the end of 2016
is now 1; the GDP deflator for years 2017–26 is now com-
puted for a 2016 base year. Then, divide nominal GDP for
all simulations by the respective GDP deflator with a 2016
base year.
21. The nominal GDP figures for the 2017–26 simulation
period are $2,214 billion for the Fair model, $2,516 for the
Fair model without the Fed, $940 billion for the Moody’s
model, and $1,735 billion for the Moody’s model without
the Fed.
22. Both models also have separate indexes for housing prices.
Results for housing price inflation were not included in the
discussion because the impact of the student debt cancel-
lation on housing prices was essentially negligible in both
models.
23. Zandi et al. (2016) report that the less-positive macro-
economic results from their simulation of Mr. Trump’s
economic proposals are strongly affected by the fact that
the national debt-to-GDP ratio rises substantially, thus
raising long-term interest rates and slowing the economy.
Interestingly, Peter Navarro, an economics professor at the
University of California-Irvine criticized Moody’s report
as “Keynesian (see Cox 2016) even though the national
debt-to-GDP ratio effects on interest rates are not part
of traditional Keynesian economics but rather part of the
“Classical” long-run “core” of the Moody’s model.
24. In terms of the econometrics, Moody’s reports an
R-squared of 0.98 for its estimation of the 10-year Treasury
note that includes the national debt-to-GDP ratio (Zandi
et al. 2016, 11), whereas Fair obtains an essentially identical
fit (R-square = 0.97) without including the national debt-
to-GDP ratio as an explanatory variable.
25. The authors offer their thanks to one of the reviewers for
pointing this out.
26. The authors wish to thank a reviewer for pointing out the
offsetting effect of improving state budgets on the consoli-
dated federal- and state-level budget positions.
27. “Normal” here is taken to mean a corridor system as
depicted in Figure C.2, which has become a standard
approach to modeling central bank operations in inter-
bank markets in the literatures published by central banks
and in academic journals. In reality, the Fed did not have
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 63
the authority to pay interest on reserve balances until
after the failure of Lehman in the fall of 2008. In that case,
the demand for reserve balances in Figure C.2 would not
have a flat portion at the interest on reserve balances and
would instead continue downward to the horizontal axis.
The Fed’s plan, though, is that eventually there will be a
return to “normal” that will look like the graph in Figure
C.2, which is also illustrative of the approach of many other
central banks prior to 2008.
28. Reserve requirements are typically represented via a more
horizontal portion of the demand for reserve balances at
RB*. Because banks can meet reserve requirements over a
two-week maintenance period, they can trade off balances
held across days and on any given day do not necessarily
have a vertical demand curve at the target rate. By the end
of the maintenance period, however, a more vertical curve
like that in Figure C.1 is more applicable, since at that point
banks have far less ability to offset surpluses or excesses in
meeting reserve requirements.
29. In practice, due to a number of factors beyond the scope of
the analysis here, it is possible for i
fedfunds
to rise above i
penalty
before banks turn to the discount window to relieve a defi-
ciency in reserve balances.
30. The Fed’s abilities to reduce reserve balances are limited
by the need to support the payments system and reserve
requirements—consistent with the text, not providing suf-
ficient reserve balances for both sources of demand simply
results in a de facto interest rate target equal to i
penalty
as the
necessary reserve balances are supplied at that rate as banks
borrow from their regional Fed banks.
31. Figure C.4 is consistent with publications by Federal
Reserve researchers. See, for instance, Ihrig, Meade, and
Weinbach (2015).
64 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
References
Addo, F. R. 2014. “Debt, Cohabitation, and Marriage in Young
Adulthood. Demography 51(5): 1677–701.
Akers, E. J., and M. M. Chingos. 2014. “Student Loan Update:
A First Look at the 2013 Survey of Consumer Finances.
Brookings Institution, Brown Center on Education Policy.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Albuquerque, B., and G. Krustev. 2015. “Debt Overhang and
Deleveraging in the US Household Sector: Gauging
the Impact on Consumption. European Central Bank
Working Paper No. 1843. Frankfurt am Main: European
Central Bank.
Ambrose, B. W., L. Cordell, and S. Ma. 2015. The Impact of
Student Loan Debt on Small Business Formation. Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper No. 15-26,
July. Philadelphia: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
Baum, S. 2016. Student Debt: Rhetoric and Realities of
Higher Education Financing. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave
MacMillan.
Bettinger, E. 2004. “How Financial Aid Affects Persistence.
In C. M. Hoxby (ed.), College Choices: The Economics of
Where to Go, When to Go, and How to Pay for It. Chicago:
NBER and University of Chicago Press.
Blanchard, O., and D. Leigh. 2013. “Growth Forecast Errors
and Fiscal Multipliers. International Monetary Fund
Working Paper No. 13/1. Washington, DC: International
Monetary Fund.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2016.
“Federal Reserve Board announces Reserve Bank income
and expense data and transfers to the Treasury for 2015.
Press release, January 11.
Bozick, R., and A. Estacion. 2014. “Do student loans delay mar-
riage? Debt repayment and family formation in young
adulthood. Demographic Research 30(69): 1865–91.
Brown, M., and S. Caldwell. 2013. “Student Loan Borrowers
Retreat From Housing and Auto Markets. The Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, Liberty Street Economics. April 17.
Brown, M., A. Haughwout, D. Lee, J. Scally, and W. van
der Klaauw. 2014. “Measuring Student Debt and Its
Performance.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff
Report No. 668. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of
New York.
Carrillo, R., R. Grey, N. Tankus, and R. Hockett. Forthcoming.
“The Legality of Student Loan Purchase and Forgiveness
by the Federal Reserve. Clarke Business Law Institute,
Program on the Law and Regulation of Financial
Institutions and Markets. Cornell University.
CFPB (Consumer Financial Protection Bureau). 2013.
“Student Loan Affordability, Analysis of Public Input on
Impact and Solutions. Online report, May 8.
http://files.consumerfinance.gov/f/201305_cfpb_rfi-report_
student-loans.pdf.
———. 2012. “Private Student Loans. Report to the Senate
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs,
the Senate Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and
Pensions, the House of Representatives Committee on
Financial Services, and the House of Representatives
Committee on Education and the Workforce. August 29.
http://files.consumerfinance.gov/f/201207_cfpb_Reports_
Private-Student-Loans.pdf.
Chakrabarti, R., M. Mabutas, and B. Zafar. 2012. “Soaring
Tuitions: Are Public Funding Cuts to Blame?” Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, Liberty Street Economics.
September 19.
Clark, B., C. Joubert, and A. Maurel. 2014. “The Career
Prospects of Overeducated Americans. IZA Discussion
Paper No. 8313. Bonn: Institute of Labor Economics.
Cox, J. 2016. Trump’s Policies Will Not Cause Recession—
Economist. CNBC.com, June 27.
Darolia, R., and D. Ritter. 2015. “Do Student Loan Borrowers
Opportunistically Default? Evidence from Bankruptcy
Reform. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working
Paper 15-17R. Philadelphia: Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia.
Dwyer, R. E., L. McCloud, and R. Hodson. 2013. “Gender,
Debt, and Dropping Out of College. Gender & Society
27(1): 30–55.
———. 2012. “Debt and Graduation from American
Universities. Social Forces 90(4): 1133–55.
Dynarski, S. M. 2016. “The trouble with student loans?
Low earnings, not high debt. Evidence Speaks Report.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
———. 2003. “Does Aid Matter?” American Economic Review
93(1): 279–88.
Edmiston, K. D., L. Brooks, and S. Shepelwich. 2013. “Student
Loans: Overview and Issues (Update). Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City Research Working Paper 12-05.
Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 65
Eichengreen, B., and K. O’Rourke. 2012. “Gauging the
Multiplier—Lessons from History. Vox EU, October 23.
Elliot, W., M. Grintstein-Weiss, and I. Nam. 2013. “Is Student
Debt Compromising Homeownership as a Wealth
Building Tool?” Center for Social Development Working
Paper No. 13-33. St. Louis, MO: Washington University in
St. Louis.
Elliott, W., and I. Nam. 2013. “Is Student Debt Jeopardizing the
Short-Term Financial Health of U.S. Households?” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review 95(5): 405–24.
Emmons, W. R., and B. J. Neoth. 2015. “Why didn’t higher
education protect Hispanic and black wealth?” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, In the Balance, Issue 12-2015.
Fair, R. 2015. “Reflections on Macroeconometric Modeling.
The B. E. Journal of Macroeconomics 15(1): 445–66.
———. 2013. “Macroeconometric Modeling. Unpublished
manuscript, November 11. Available at: https://fairmodel.
econ.yale.edu/mmm2/mm.pdf.
———. 2007. “Evaluating Inflation Targeting Using a
Macroeconometric Model. Economics: The Open-Access,
Open-Assessment E-Journal 1(2007–8): 1–52.
———. 2004. Estimating How the Macroeconomy Works.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
———. 2000. “Fed Policy and the Effects of a Stock Market
Crash on the Economy. Business Economics 35(2): 7–14.
———. 1992. “The Cowles Commission Approach, Real
Business Cycle Theories, and New Keynesian Economics.
In M. T. Belongia and M. R. Garfinkel (eds.), The Business
Cycle: Theories and Evidence—Proceedings of the 16th
Annual Economic Policy Conference of the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Federal Reserve. 2016. “Consumer Credit, G.19 Statistical
Release. Released April 2016.
GAO (Government Accountability Office). 2014. “Federal
Student Loans: Borrower Interest Rates Cannot Be
Set in Advance to Precisely and Consistently Balance
Federal Revenues and Costs. Report to Congressional
Committees. GAO-14-234. Washington, DC. January.
———. 2001. “Department of Education: Key Aspects of the
Federal Direct Loan Programs Cost Estimates. Report to
Congressional Requesters. GAO-01-197. Washington, DC.
January.
Goldin, C., and L. F. Katz. 2010. The Race between Education
and Technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Goodfriend, M. 2014. The Relevance of Federal Reserve
Surplus Capital for Current Policy. Economics 21,
Manhattan Institute for Policy Research, March 17.
Huelsman, M. 2015a. The Debt Divide: The Racial and Class
Bias Behind the ‘New Normal’ of Student Borrowing.
Online report. New York: Demos.
———. 2015b. “The Case for Debt-Free College. Online
report. New York: Demos.
Ihrig, J. E., E. E. Meade, and G. C. Weinbach. 2015. “Monetary
Policy 101—A Primer on the Fed’s Changing Approach
to Policy Implementation. Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2015-047. Washington, DC: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Li, W. 2013. “The Economics of Student Loan Borrowing
and Repayment. Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Business Review Q3.
Looney, A., and C. Yannelis. 2015. A crisis in student loans?
How changes in the characteristics of borrowers and
in the institutions they attended contributed to rising
loan defaults. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
McMillan Cottom, T. 2017. Lower Ed: The Troubling Rise of
For-Profit Colleges in the New Economy. New York, NY: The
New Press.
MeasureOne. 2015. The MeasureOne Q3 2015 Private Student
Loan Report. Accessed June 12, 2016.
Mezza, A., D. R. Ringo, S. M. Sherlund, and K. Sommer.
2016. “On the Effect of Student Loans on Access to
Homeownership. Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2016-010. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.
Mueller, H. M., and C. Yannelis. 2017. “Students in Distress:
Labor Market Shocks, Student Loan Default, and Federal
Insurance Programs. NBER Working Paper No. 23284.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
NCES (National Center on Educational Statistics). 2015.
“Digest of Education Statistics, 2015. US Department
of Education. https://nces.ed.gov/programs/
digest/2015menu_tables.asp.
66 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018
Vandenbroucke, G. 2015. “Lifetime Benefits of an Education
Have Never Been So High. Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis, The Regional Economist July: 10–11.
Weissmann, J. 2016. “Forgiving All Student Loan Debt Would
Be an Awful, Regressive Idea. Slate, August 15.
Woo, J., A. Bentz, S. Lew, N. Smith, and E. D. Velez. 2017.
“Repayment of Student Loans as of 2015 among 1995–96
and 2003–04 First-Time Beginning Students. First Look,
NCES 2018-410. Washington, DC: National Center for
Education Statistics.
Zahn, M. 2014. The Impact of Youth Debt on College
Graduation. Journal of Sociology and Social Welfare 41(3):
133–56.
Zandi, M. 2008. Assessing the Macroeconomic Impact of
Fiscal Stimulus 2008. Moody’s Economy.com.
Zandi, M., and S. Hoyt. 2015. “US Macro Model Methodology.
Moody’s Analytics—Economic and Consumer Credit
Analytics. April.
Zandi, M., C. Lafakis, and A. Ozimek. 2016. The
Macroeconomic Consequences of Secretary Clintons
Economic Policies. Moody’s Analytics. July.
Zandi, M., C. Lafakis, D. White, and A. Ozimek. 2016. “The
Macroeconomic Consequences of Mr. Trump’s Economic
Policies. Moody’s Analytics. June.
———. 2014. “Digest of Education Statistics, 2014. US
Department of Education. https://nces.ed.gov/programs/
digest/2014menu_tables.asp.
———. 2013. “2011–12 National Postsecondary Student
Aid Study (NPSAS: 12). US Department of Education.
Computation by NCES QuickStats on April 13, 2016.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development). 2015. “Education at a Glance, Tables A7.4a
and A7.4b. OECD Indicators. Paris: OECD.
Schwartz, J. 2005. “The Socio-Economic Benefits of Marriage:
A Review of Recent Evidence from the United States.
Economics Affairs 25(3): 45–51.
SHEEO (State Higher Education Executive Officers
Association). 2015. “SHEF: FY 2015, State Higher
Education Finance. Boulder, CO: State Higher Education
Executive Officers Association.
Steinbaum, M., and K. Vaghul. 2016. “How the student debt
crisis affects African Americans and Latinos. Online
report. Washington, DC: Washington Center for Equitable
Growth.
———. 2015. An introduction to the geography of student
debt. Washington, DC: Washington Center for Equitable
Growth.
———. Forthcoming. The Student Loan Crisis is a Labor
Market Crisis.
US Census Bureau. CPS Historical Time Series Tables, Table
A-2. “Percent of People 25 Years and Over Who Have
Completed High School or College, by Race, Hispanic
Origin and Sex: Selected Years 1940 to 2015. Accessed on
June 11, 2016. https://www.census.gov/data/tables/
time-series/demo/educational-attainment/cps-historical-
time-series.html.
———. Historical Income Tables: Households, Table H-9.
“Race of Head of Household by Median and Mean
Income. Accessed on June 11, 2016. https://www.census.
gov/data/tables/time-series/demo/income-poverty/
historical-income-households.html.
US Department of Education. 2017. “Comparison of FY 2014
Official National Cohort Default Rates to Prior Two
Official Cohort Default Rates, Calculated August 5, 2017.
https://www2.ed.gov/offices/OSFAP/defaultmanagement/
schooltyperates.pdf.
———. 2016. “Understanding Delinquency and Default.
Accessed June 12. https://studentaid.ed.gov/sa/
repay-loans/default.
Levy Economics Institute of Bard College 67
of Bard College
Levy Economics
Institute
The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College,
founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan,
research organization
devoted to public service.
Through scholarship and research
it generates viable,
effective public policy responses to
important economic problems
that profoundly affect the quality of life
in the United States and abroad.
levy economics institute of bard college
Blithewood
Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000
845-758-7700
E-mail: info@lev y.org
levyinstitute.org
©2018 Levy Economics Institute of Bard College
68 Student Debt Cancellation Report 2018